Skip to main content
U.S. flag

An official website of the United States government

Dot gov

The .gov means it’s official.
Federal government websites often end in .gov or .mil. Before sharing sensitive information, make sure you’re on a federal government site.

Https

The site is secure.
The https:// ensures that you are connecting to the official website and that any information you provide is encrypted and transmitted securely.

Modeling the Decision to Purchase Private Long-Term Care Insurance

Publication Date

U.S. Department of Health and Human Services

Modeling the Decision to Purchase Private Long-Term Care Insurance

RIchard W. Johnson, Simone G. Schaner, Desmond Toohey, and Cori E. Uccello

The Urban Institute

January 2007

PDF Version: http://aspe.hhs.gov/daltcp/reports/2007/LTCImod.pdf (60 PDF pages)


This report was prepared under contract between the U.S. Department of Health and Human Services (HHS), Office of Disability, Aging and Long-Term Care Policy (DALTCP) and the Urban Institute. For additional information about this subject, you can visit the DALTCP home page at http://aspe.hhs.gov/_/office_specific/daltcp.cfm or contact the ASPE Project Officer, John Drabek, at HHS/ASPE/DALTCP, Room 424E, H.H. Humphrey Building, 200 Independence Avenue, S.W., Washington, D.C. 20201. His e-mail address is: John.Drabek@hhs.gov.

The authors are grateful to Jim Robinson of the University of Wisconsin-Madison for generously providing us with his actuarial model of long-term care services use, Jon Bakija of Williams College for generously providing us with his federal and state income tax calculator, and Marc Cohen, John Drabek, Amy Finkelstein, Mark Pauly, and especially Peter Kemper for valuable comments on an earlier draft. The views expressed here are those of the authors and should not be attributed to the U.S. Department of Health and Human Services or the Urban Institute, its board, or its funders.


TABLE OF CONTENTS

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY

I. INTRODUCTION

II. HOW DOES PRIVATE LONG-TERM CARE INSURANCE WORK?

Pricing

Lapse Rates

III. WHO BUYS LONG-TERM CARE INSURANCE?

Previous Literature

Limitations of Existing Studies

IV. METHODOLOGICAL APPROACH

V. DATA AND MEASURES

Health and Retirement Study

Computing the Net Expected Benefit of Coverage

Other Measures

Sample Characteristics

VI. MODEL ESTIMATES AND POLICY SIMULATIONS

Policy Simulations

VII. CONCLUSIONS

REFERENCES

NOTES

LIST OF TABLES

TABLE II-1: Mean Annual Premiums Among Policies Purchased in 2002, by Age and Inflation Protection

TABLE II-2: Voluntary Long-Term Care Insurance Lapse Rates, by Selected Characteristics, 2000-2001

TABLE III-1: Characteristics of Individual Long-Term Care Insurance Buyers, Nonbuyers, and the General Population Age 55 and Older, 2000

TABLE III-2: Opinions About Long-Term Care Among Buyers and Nonbuyers of Individual Long-Term Care Insurance Age 55 and Over, 2000

TABLE V-1: Buyer Profiles, Age 55 and Older, 2000 and 2002

TABLE V-2: Share of Noninstitutionalized Population Age 55 and Older with Given Characteristic and Share with Private Long-Term Care Insurance Coverage, 2002

TABLE V-3: Share of Noninstitutionalized Population Age 55 and Older with Private Long-Term Care Insurance Coverage, by Economic Status and Age, 2002

TABLE V-4: Average Annual Premiums in the Individual Long-Term Care Insurance Market, by State and Selected Issue Age, 2002

TABLE V-5: State Income Tax Deductions and Credits for Private Long-Term Care Insurance, 2002

TABLE V-6: Average Nursing Costs and Home Health Care Costs, by State, 2002

TABLE V-7: Medicaid Eligibility Standards, Personal Needs Allowance, and Spousal Impoverishment Resource Limits for Institutionalized Individuals, by State, 2001/2002

TABLE V-8: Medicaid Eligibility Rates for Home and Community-Based Care for Aged Adults, by State, 2001/2002

TABLE V-9: Descriptive Statistics of Variables in Logit Models

TABLE VI-1: Estimated Odds Ratios of the Purchase of Private Long-Term Care Insurance, with Standard Errors in Parentheses

TABLE VI-2: Share of Adults Age 63-73 in 2004 Who Took Up Private Long-Term Care Insurance Coverage Between 1992 and 2004, Under Current Law and Alternative Policy Scenarios

TABLE VI-3: Impact of Long-Term Care Insurance Policy Reforms on Medicaid-Financed Nursing Home Care

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY

Long-term care spending is expected to soar in coming decades as the population ages. Enhanced private insurance coverage of long-term care needs might ease the looming crisis. Raising private insurance coverage rates would increase the pool of funds set aside to finance future services and would reduce reliance on public resources. Enhanced private coverage could also protect families from catastrophic long-term care costs. Some policymakers have proposed expanding tax incentives for private long-term care coverage to stimulate demand.

To assess how different tax break proposals for private long-term care insurance might affect private coverage, we need better information on the decision to purchase long-term care insurance and the sensitivity of the purchase decision to price changes. This report describes the results of our efforts to model private long-term care insurance coverage and simulate policy reforms.

Background

Like traditional medical insurance, private long-term care insurance is a financial contract whereby the insurer agrees to provide covered benefits in exchange for regular premium payments by the policyholder. The cost and adequacy of policies vary by the types of services they cover, when they start paying benefits, how much they pay, and for how long.

Insurance companies generally price policies as a function of age at issue date, health status, and the comprehensiveness of the plan. Most insurers classify applicants into three broad health categories: preferred, standard, and substandard. Most applicants qualify for standard rates, although according to one estimate 15 percent are denied coverage because of health problems. Policies are guaranteed renewable, and premiums remain fixed over the life of the contract. However, rates can rise for an entire class of policyholders if insurers can demonstrate that their costs exceed premium revenue, and rate increases have been common in recent years.

Methods

There are two principal challenges in modeling the decision to purchase private long-term care insurance, particularly the effect of prices on take-up rates. First, at any age uncovered individuals who live in the same state generally face the same premiums, making it difficult to observe how coverage rates vary with price, controlling for age and state of residence. Second, covered people deciding whether to renew their policies face lower premiums than otherwise identical people without coverage deciding whether to purchase a policy for the first time. This relationship could bias the estimated impact of price on the coverage decision.

The analysis addressed these complexities by estimating hazard models of time to purchase private long-term care insurance as a function of the net benefit that individuals expect to derive from the policy. The net expected benefit is the difference between what policyholders expect to receive in benefit payouts from the plan over their lifetimes, in present value terms, and what they expect to pay into the plan in the form of premiums. The measure, which accounted for state-level fluctuations in premiums and Medicaid eligibility rules, varied widely across individuals. Respondents were dropped from the sample once they purchased coverage, eliminating the correlation between premiums and past purchase decisions. Observing purchase decisions over an extended period, beginning when respondents were relatively young, reduced the censoring problem that would otherwise result if we modeled only cases that had not yet purchased coverage at relatively old ages (and thus had revealed their reluctance to obtain coverage).

Data came primarily from the Health and Retirement Study (HRS), a nationally representative longitudinal survey of older Americans. The survey asks respondents whether they have any long-term care insurance (excluding government programs) that covers nursing home care for a year or more or some at-home personal or medical care, and when they purchased the policy. Follow-up questions added in 2002 ask whether the respondent had already described the plan to the interviewer, such as when reporting traditional health insurance plans, and if so to identify the plan. After reclassifying respondents as lacking private long-term care coverage if they described their private long-term care insurance policies as traditional health plans, Medicaid, or Medicare, we found that coverage rates in the HRS were consistent with industry estimates.

The sample consisted of person-year observations between 1992 and 2004 on adults ages 51-61 in 1992 who did not have coverage in the previous year. We observed respondents every other year. We restricted our sample to respondents likely to satisfy long-term care insurers’ underwriting restrictions and thus able to purchase private coverage. We dropped respondents who reported any activity of daily living or instrumental activity of living limitations, kidney problems, history of stroke, or cognitive impairment, and who were not living in nursing homes. In 1992, about 5 percent of respondents were dropped from the sample because they reported one of these health problems. The share increased over time as the sample aged, rising to 32 percent in 2002. Overall, 17 percent of the person-year observations were dropped because of health problems or nursing home residence. The final sample consisted of 32,242 observations on 6,991 respondents.

Model Estimates

The net expected benefit of coverage significantly increased the likelihood of taking-up private long-term care insurance coverage, although the impact was modest.

  • Every $1,000 increase in the net expected benefit of coverage would raise purchase probabilities by about 2.3 percent.

  • Under the assumption that premium changes have the same effect on take-up rates as changes in expected out-of-pocket payments for services, this result implies a price elasticity of demand for private long-term care insurance of about -0.75.

  • Take-up rates also increased with age, education, health status, and the self-assessed probability of using nursing home care in the next years. They declined with number of children, perhaps because children help with their parents’ home care or help finance nursing home costs.

Policy Simulations

Creating additional federal tax incentives for the purchase of private long-term care insurance would modestly boost take-up rates.

  • Granting a full tax deduction to all itemizers, even those who spend less than 7.5 percent of adjusted gross income on medical expenses, would raise take-up rates by about 3 percentage points, from 14 percent to 17 percent, increasing the number of adults with coverage by about 21 percent.

  • Take-up rates would rise to 19 percent if all taxpayers could fully deduct premium expenses from income subject to federal income taxes, representing about a 36 percent boost in the number of older adults with coverage.

  • The impact of tax incentives on private long-term care insurance would be concentrated among high-income taxpayers. Tax breaks would have very little impact on coverage rates for adults in the bottom half of the income distribution.

I. INTRODUCTION

As the population ages, long-term care spending is expected to soar in coming decades. National health expenditures projections from the Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services indicate that nursing home and home health costs will rise from $151 billion in 2003 to $291 billion in 2014 (Heffler et al. 2005). Costs are likely to grow even more rapidly in about 20 years when the oldest members of the baby boom cohort, born in the years following World War II, enter their 80s, a decade of life when many people need assistance with basic personal activities. Rising long-term care costs threaten older Americans’ retirement security. For example, more than one in 20 people now turning 65 will likely spend at least $100,000 out-of-pocket (in present discounted value) on long-term care (Kemper, Komisar, and Alecxih 2005/2006). Rising costs also create financial problems for Medicare and Medicaid, which now fund about 60 percent of long-term care expenditures (Congressional Budget Office 2004).

Enhanced private insurance coverage of long-term care needs might ease the looming crisis. Raising private insurance coverage rates would increase the pool of funds set aside to finance future services and would reduce reliance on public resources. Enhanced private coverage could also protect families from catastrophic long-term care costs.

Although the private long-term care insurance market has grown rapidly in recent years, relatively few Americans have coverage. To encourage more people to purchase policies, some policymakers have proposed expanding tax incentives for those with private long-term care coverage. Under current law, individuals can deduct premium expenses for qualified long-term care plans from their taxable income only if their total medical expenses (including premiums) exceed 7.5 percent of adjusted gross income. And the amount that can be deducted is capped. Extending tax breaks to all policyholders and allowing the full deductibility of premium costs would lower the after-tax price of long-term care policies for some consumers, and could significantly raise coverage rates.

To assess how different tax break proposals for private long-term care insurance might affect private coverage, we need better information on the decision to purchase long-term care insurance and the sensitivity of the purchase decision to price changes. This report describes the results of our efforts to model private long-term care insurance coverage and simulate policy reforms.

The report is organized as follows. The next two chapters provide background on private long-term care insurance, first describing how policies work and how much they tend to cost, and then describing who buys them. Chapter 4 discusses our methodological approach. Chapter 5 describes the data and the measures we construct from them. Chapter 6 reports the model estimates and results from our policy simulations. The final chapter presents conclusions. Tables follow several chapters.

The findings show that extending tax breaks for private long-term care insurance could modestly expand coverage. In 2004 about 14 percent of adults ages 63-73 had purchased private long-term care insurance at some point since 1992. Because the purchase decision responds to price changes, reforming the tax law to allow all policyholders to deduct their premium expenses from taxable income would raise purchase rates by about one-third.

II. HOW DOES PRIVATE LONG-TERM CARE INSURANCE WORK?

Like traditional medical insurance, private long-term care insurance is a financial contract whereby the insurer agrees to provide covered benefits in exchange for regular premium payments by the policyholder. The long-term care insurance market has grown steadily over the past 20 years. First sold as nursing home insurance in the 1970s, it now covers a wide range of services, including home care, adult day care, and assisted living, in addition to nursing home care. The cumulative number of long-term care insurance policies purchased has increased from fewer than 1 million in 1987 to over 9 million by the end of 2002, but still covers only a small share of the population (America’s Health Insurance Plans (AHIP) 2004).

Long-term care insurance can be purchased through either the individual or group market. Group plans are typically sponsored, but not subsidized, by employers. Individual policies continue to dominate the market, but employer-sponsored plans are growing rapidly, fueled in part by the creation of the Federal Long-Term Care Insurance Program in 2002, which allows federal employees, retirees, and some of their family members to purchase coverage through the Federal Government. In addition to offering group coverage to 20 million eligible Americans, the federal program could also encourage other employers to sponsor long-term care insurance. In 2006, 12 percent of all private-sector workers (and 20 percent of workers at private establishments with 100 or more employees) had access to long-term care insurance at work (U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics 2006). About one-third of new policies sold in 2002 were sponsored by employers. By contrast, only 18 percent of policies ever sold by 2002 were employer-sponsored plans (AHIP 2004).

The cost and adequacy of policies vary by the types of services they cover, when they start paying benefits, how much they pay, and for how long. About three-quarters (77 percent) of individual policies purchased in 2000 covered both nursing homes and home care (LifePlans, Inc. 2000). In 1990, by contrast, nearly two-thirds of policies sold covered only nursing home care.

Benefit Triggers. Policyholders cannot collect benefits until their disabilities reach the levels specified in their contracts. About nine in ten plans now sold use the triggers specified in the Health Insurance Portability and Accountability Act (HIPAA) of 1996 to qualify for tax breaks (AHIP 2004). These plans require that beneficiaries need substantial assistance with at least two out of six activities of daily living (ADLs) and that their disabilities are expected to last 90 or more days, or that they need regular supervision because of severe cognitive impairment. (Benefits paid to policyholders who do not meet the HIPAA criteria are subject to federal income tax.)

Elimination Period. Most plans impose deductibles by delaying benefits for a period of time after the onset of a qualified disability. Among comprehensive policies purchased in 2000 (covering both nursing home and home care), the average elimination period, as it is known, was 47 days (LifePlans, Inc. 2000). Among nursing home-only plans, the average elimination period was 65 days. Just about half of all plans purchased in 2000 imposed an elimination period of between 90 and 100 days; only 3 percent stipulated elimination periods longer than 100 days. However, nearly one-quarter of policies purchased in 2000 did not impose any elimination period, and instead promised to pay benefits immediately upon the onset of a qualified disability.

The elimination period may be computed on the basis of service days, rather than calendar days (Center for Medicare Education 2004). Under the service day method, only days spent in nursing homes with a qualified disability count toward satisfying the elimination period. Days spent with a qualified disability outside a nursing home do not count.

Daily Benefit Amount. Policies limit how much they will pay per day of nursing home care and home care. In 2000, the average nursing home daily benefit was $109 (LifePlans, Inc. 2000). By comparison, the average nursing facility rate was $150 per day in 2001 (AARP 2002) and $192 per day in 2004 (MetLife 2004). Only 23 percent of policies sold in 2000 limited the nursing home daily benefit to less than $90; 34 percent of policies set the limit above $120. Daily benefits for home care are now comparable to nursing home benefits. In 2000, the average home care daily benefit was $106, and one-third of plans provided benefits of more than $120 per day (LifePlans, Inc. 2000). In 1990, policies generally set the home care benefit equal to one-half the nursing home benefit.

Benefit Escalation. A critical determinant of the adequacy of long-term care coverage is the extent to which the daily benefit amount grows over time. Since policyholders often purchase coverage decades before they receive benefits, the growth in nominal long-term care costs can erode the value of the policy. In 2000, 41 percent of new buyers purchased inflation protection, up from 33 percent in 1995 (Cohen, Weinrobe, and Miller 2002). Inflation protection is especially common at relatively young ages. For example, 59 percent of new buyers ages 55-64 purchased inflation protection in 2000, compared with only 32 percent of those ages 70-74.

Inflation protection generally takes the form of a fixed percentage increase per year, typically 5 percent annually (Cohen, Weinrobe, and Miller 2002). Benefit escalators are not usually tied to changes in some price index. Policyholders can generally choose between having benefits increase on a compounded basis or a simple interest basis. In 2000, 22 percent of new buyers chose the inflation protection with the compounded option, and 17 percent chose protection with the simple percentage increase option.

Duration of Benefits. About one-third of plans (30 percent in 2000) provide lifetime benefits (LifePlans, Inc. 2000). Most policies, however, limit periods to a specified number of years. Among policies purchased in 2000, 17 percent limited nursing home benefits to one or two years, 23 percent imposed a three-year limit, 14 percent imposed a four-year limit, and 16 percent limited benefits to five or six years. Among plans with time limits, the average duration of nursing home benefits was 5.5 years. The distribution of limits was similar for home care benefits.

Pricing

Insurance companies generally price policies as a function of age at issue date, health status, and the comprehensiveness of the plan (Brown and Finkelstein 2004b). Most insurers classify applicants into three broad health categories: preferred, standard, and substandard. Most applicants qualify for standard rates, although according to one estimate 15 percent are denied coverage because of health problems (Weiss Ratings, Inc. 2002). Policies are guaranteed renewable, and rates do not increase in response to a health decline for a given individual. Instead, once the policy is purchased, premiums remain fixed in nominal terms over the life of the contract. However, premiums can rise for an entire class of policyholders if insurers can demonstrate that their costs exceed premium revenue, and rate increases have been common in recent years. Premiums do not generally differ by gender (Finkelstein and McGarry 2006), even though women exhibit higher long-term-care utilization rates than men. Some plans offer discounts to married policyholders when their spouses are also covered.

Table II-1 reports mean annual premiums for policies sold in 2002, by the age of the policyholder and the presence of inflation protection. Prices refer to a policy that provides up to four years of benefits, with a $150 daily benefit and a 90-day elimination period. The inflation protection option increases benefits by 5 percent per year, compounded annually. Premiums vary dramatically by age. The mean annual premium for 40-year-olds who declined inflation protection was $422. The mean annual premiums for the same policy was $564 at age 50, $1,337 at age 65, and $5,330 at age 79. For policies purchased at ages 40 and 50, the inflation protection option more than doubles the annual premium. For coverage purchased at age 79, inflation protection increases premiums by less than half.

Brown and Finkelstein (2004b) find that private long-term care insurance policies are generally priced higher than the actuarially fair level for men, but lower than the actuarially fair level for women, who are much more likely to utilize benefits. The typical load factor for men was 0.44, implying that male policyholders can only expect to receive 56 cents in benefits for every dollar they spend on premiums. For women, the typical load factor was -0.04, implying that they can expect $1.04 in benefits for every dollar they spend on premiums.

Lapse Rates

When modeling participation in long-term care insurance plans, it is also important to incorporate assumptions regarding policy lapses. A substantial share of purchasers drop their coverage within a few years of purchase (McNamara and Lee 2004). Unless these individuals replace these policies with other plans, they will not have private insurance to fund any long-term care needs.

The Society of Actuaries (SOA) has conducted persistency studies on long-term care insurance using administrative data gathered from long-term care insurance carriers. Their most recent study, done in conjunction with LIMRA (2004), examined persistency and lapse rates during 2000 and 2001. They found overall voluntary lapse rates (that is, those resulting from reasons other than death) of 5.4 percent, down from the 7.6 percent rate experienced between 1984 and 1999.1

Lapse rates varied considerably by policy and insured characteristics (Table II-2). In particular, lapse rates declined with the duration of the policy, especially for group policies. Lapse rates for group policies exceeded 14 percent for each of the first two policy years, then decreased gradually, falling to about 3 percent or less after policy year ten. Lapse rates for individual policies fell below those of group policies in the initial years, but slightly exceeded the individual lapse rates in policy year nine and beyond.

Lapse rates also decreased with age, and were especially high for individuals younger than 45. Lapse rates for men and women were very similar, but unmarried policyholders had somewhat higher lapse rates. Interestingly, policyholders with a standard risk classification have somewhat higher lapse rates than those in the preferred risk category, as well as those in the substandard risk category.

More generous plan design features were associated with lower-than-average lapse rates. For instance, policyholders with a lifetime benefit maximum over $100,000 were less than half as likely to lapse than those with higher lifetime maximums. In addition, policyholders with inflation protection were less likely to lapse. It is unclear from the LIMRA/SOA study whether policyholders who voluntarily terminated their policies replaced them with other policies. Higher lapse rates for less generous policies could reflect the tendency of these policyholders to replace their plans with more generous coverage. Or, it could be that individuals with fewer financial resources purchase less generous plans, and then are forced to drop them because they are unable to keep up with the premiums.2

  TABLE II-1. Mean Annual Premiums Among Policies Purchased in 2002, By Age and Inflation Protection ($)  
  Age     No Inflation Protection     With Inflation Protection  
40 422 890
50 564 1,134
65 1,337 2,346
79 5,330 7,572
SOURCE: AHIP (2004). NOTE: Prices refer to a policy that provides up to four years of benefits, with a $150 daily benefit and a 90-day elimination period. The inflation protection option increases benefits by 5 percent per year, compounded annually.
TABLE II-2. Voluntary Long-Term Care Insurance Lapse Rates, by Selected Characteristics, 2000-2001
    All Plans     Individual Plans     Group Plans  
OVERALL 5.4 4.2 8.9
POLICY YEAR
   1 8.5 6.2 14.9
   2 7.4 5.0 14.3
   3 4.9 3.7 9.7
   4 3.9 3.0 7.3
   5 3.5 2.7 5.7
   6 3.3 2.7 4.9
   7 3.6 3.0 4.6
   8 3.9 3.2 5.4
   9 3.2 3.3 3.0
   10 3.0 3.8 1.7
ATTAINED AGE
   35 NA 13.3 16.5
   40 NA 9.7 12.0
   45 NA 7.4 9.4
   50 NA 5.5 7.6
   55 NA 4.4 5.8
   60 NA 3.9 4.7
   65 NA 4.3 3.9
   70 NA 3.8 1.4
   75 NA 4.0 1.3
   80 NA 4.4 1.8
   85 NA 4.9 1.7
GENDER
   Male 5.6 NA NA
   Female 5.2 NA NA
MARITAL STATUS AT ISSUE
   Married 3.5 NA NA
   Unmarried 5.8 NA NA
RISK CLASSIFICATION
   Standard 5.9 NA NA
   Preferred 4.2 NA NA
  Substandard 4.7 NA NA
LIFETIME BENEFIT MAXIMUM
   Under $100,000 14.7 NA NA
   $100,000-$250,000 7.2 NA NA
   Over $250,000 4.6 NA NA
LIFETIME BENEFIT MAXIMUM (Period)
   Up to 5 years 4.1 NA NA
   Over 5 years 3.6 NA NA
INFLATION PROTECTION
   None 7.0 NA NA
   Future purchase options 4.1 NA NA
   Automatic annual increase 4.7 NA NA
SOURCE: LIMRA/SOA (2004).

III. WHO BUYS LONG-TERM CARE INSURANCE?

A few existing studies examine who purchases private long-term care insurance coverage and the factors influencing their decisions. However, data problems limit many of these studies, and only one attempts to estimate the price elasticity of demand for long-term care insurance, which is critical for assessing the likely impact of tax breaks on coverage rates.

Previous Literature

LifePlans, Inc. (2000) has examined who purchases long-term care insurance, who does not, and the reasons behind their decisions. Their 2000 study compared adults ages 55 and older who purchased individual long-term care insurance coverage to “nonbuyers” -- those who had been approached by an agent or presented the details of a long-term care policy but chose not to purchase. The study also compared both groups to the general population ages 55 and older. In general, the analysis found that long-term care insurance purchasers had higher incomes and more wealth than nonbuyers and the general older population (Table III-1). For instance, whereas only one-quarter of nonbuyers and the general older population had incomes of at least $50,000, 42 percent of buyers had incomes of $50,000 or more. Differences in financial assets were even more dramatic. Seventy-one percent of buyers had financial assets exceeding $100,000, compared with only 42 percent of nonbuyers and a mere 7 percent of the general population. Long-term care insurance buyers were also better educated, more likely to be married, and more likely to be either working themselves or married to workers than nonbuyers. The average age of buyers (67) was also somewhat lower than nonbuyers (71) and the general population ages 55 and older (69).

The LifePlans analysis of buyers and nonbuyers, however, may not generalize to the entire population of long-term care insurance purchasers. Because it was limited to those who purchased individual long-term care insurance, it does not reflect the characteristics of individuals who purchased group insurance, through either an association or an employer group. According to the American Council of Life Insurers (2003), those who purchased long-term care insurance in 2001 through a group were much younger on average than those who purchased individual insurance. One-third of group long-term care insurance purchasers were 40 or younger, compared with only 3 percent of individual long-term care insurance purchasers. Other characteristics, including income and assets, likely differ between individual and group purchasers as well.

The LifePlans study also provides insights into the views of buyers and nonbuyers and the reasons behind the purchase (or nonpurchase) decision (Table III-2). Buyers and nonbuyers were fairly similar in their opinions regarding the importance of planning for possible long-term care needs and concerns about how to pay for care. Their views differed, however, on the perceived adequacy of insurance products and the proper role of government. Although nearly three-quarters of buyers believed that the insurance industry provides adequate coverage for long-term care services, only one-half of nonbuyers agreed. Nonbuyers were twice as likely as buyers (33 percent vs. 15 percent) to report that they could rely on the government to pay most of their long-term care costs.

Nearly one-third of individual long-term care insurance buyers in the LifePlans study cited protecting assets or leaving an estate as the most important reason for their purchase. This in part explains the low share of buyers with initial wealth. Other reasons cited included avoiding dependence (19 percent), protecting living standards (12 percent), and ensuring affordability of future care (14 percent). Individuals who chose to decline coverage most often cited cost as the reason. More than one-half of nonbuyers reported that coverage is too costly. Other reasons for forgoing coverage included that they were waiting for a better policy, found it hard to choose a policy, or did not believe insurers’ promises.

There have been relatively few econometric studies of private long-term care insurance coverage. Kumar et al. (1995) examined the decision to purchase coverage and the type of insurance that policyholders chose in a sample of about 6,500 individuals ages 55 and older who purchased coverage in late 1990 and early 1991 and about 1,200 individuals who had been approached by agents but chose not to purchase. Individuals were surveyed by LifePlans, Inc., after being identified by six insurers that together represented 45 percent of the individual private market. The authors estimated a two-stage model that first predicted whether an individual purchased any coverage and then predicted the expected value of coverage among policyholders. The models controlled for age, gender, marital status, education, income, assets, expected cost of long-term care for the individual, state of residence, number of children living nearby, perceived risk of using services, characteristics of the Medicaid program in the state of residence, and the risk premium charged by the policy (for those who purchased coverage).

The results indicate that younger individuals, married people, women, and those without a college education were more likely to purchase coverage than other adults ages 55 and older. Coverage rates increased significantly with income, but not with assets. Those who reported their odds of using future nursing home care as greater than 50-50 were significantly more likely to buy coverage than other people, but those who believed that they were likely to use home care were significantly less likely to purchase coverage. The presence of children reduced the odds of coverage. People were significantly less likely to purchase coverage as the state’s Medicaid per diem rate for nursing homes increased.3

Among those who purchased coverage, the risk premium charged by the policy significantly reduced the comprehensiveness of coverage. The authors computed the risk premium as the difference between the actual premium paid and the actuarially fair premium for the level-of-coverage purchased, given the individual’s age and gender. Policyholders who faced higher effective prices for coverage because they were likely to use fewer services tended to purchase less comprehensive coverage than other policyholders. The results also indicated that men tended to purchase more comprehensive coverage than women, even though men were less likely to purchase any coverage. (One possible explanation for this difference is that the level-of-coverage equations control for the risk premium, and women likely face lower risk premiums than men because they tend to use more long-term care services but premiums do not vary by gender.) The expected value of coverage was also relatively high among single people, those with college degrees, those with high incomes, and those with high expected lifetime usage of long-term care services.

Mellor (2001) used data on a sample of adults ages 70 and older in 1993 from the Health and Retirement Study (HRS) to examine the impact of unpaid caregivers on the coverage decision. She estimated probit models of the decision to purchase long-term care insurance, controlling for age, education, race, gender, marital status, household income, net worth, health status, and the presence or availability of unpaid caregivers. Not surprisingly, she found that the probability of private coverage increased significantly with income, wealth, and education. Controlling for other factors, she found that race, gender, and marital status did not significantly affect the purchase decision. (In contrast, Kumar et al. (1995) found significant effects for gender and marital status, as noted earlier.) Older adults were somewhat more likely to purchase coverage than younger adults in her sample of people ages 70 and older, but the effect was only marginally significant. Private coverage rates were not significantly affected by the presence of limitations with ADLs or instrumental activities of daily living (IADLs), although those who reported being in poor health were somewhat less likely to have coverage. Interestingly, when controlling for demographic, financial, and health characteristics, the study found that respondents who were currently receiving unpaid help or those who reported having relatives or friends who would be willing to help if they needed assistance with basic personal care in the future were not significantly less likely to report private coverage than those without access to unpaid care.

Finkelstein and McGarry (2006) used 1995 HRS data to examine private long-term care insurance coverage among adults ages 72 and older. They found that coverage rates increased with the perceived likelihood of using nursing home care, based on responses to a question asking individuals to measure the chances, on a scale from 0 to 100, that they will move to a nursing home in the next five years.

A recent study used 2002 HRS data to examine the impact of price on decisions by people ages 55 and older without private long-term care insurance to purchase coverage. Cramer and Jensen (2006) estimated logit models of the purchase decision, as functions of the annual premium, income, assets, gender, marital status, number of children, race, ethnicity, geographic region of residence, probability of living ten or more years, self-reported health status, whether they plan to leave a bequest, parental experience with long-term care, and whether they itemized deductions when filing their federal income tax returns. They used three different measures of price, each taken from industry sources: a 1996 rate schedule filed by GE Capital with the State of Michigan, 1999 rates filed by John Hancock Life Insurance with the State of New Jersey, and 2002 national insurance rate averages published by the Health Insurance Association of America. Cramer and Jensen found that the price generally had a significant but small negative effect on the likelihood of purchasing coverage, with estimated elasticities ranging from -0.23 to -0.87. Their results also indicated that well-educated adults, those who intend to leave bequests, and those who itemize their deductions are more likely to purchase coverage, whereas the number of children reduced the likelihood of coverage.

Limitations of Existing Studies

There are significant limitations to each of these studies. With the exception of Cramer and Jensen (2006), all are based on data that are now quite old, especially given the rapid growth in the private long-term care insurance market and changes in the characteristics of policyholders. For example, the average age of buyers in the individual market was 60 in 2002, down from 72 in 1990 (AHIP 2004). As a result, it is unclear how well the findings from these studies apply to today’s market conditions. In addition, it is unlikely that the sample examined by Kumar et al. (1995) is representative of the general population of older adults, because all of the respondents in that study had demonstrated some interest in purchasing long-term care insurance.

There are also problems with the questions about long-term care insurance coverage in the early years of the HRS. The 1993 survey, used by Mellor (2001), did not ask respondents specifically about long-term care insurance. Instead, it asked respondents whether they “have any (other) type of health insurance coverage,” and then the kind of coverage they have (“basic health insurance, a supplement to Medicare (MEDIGAP) or to other health insurance, long-term care insurance, or what?”). Only 2 percent of respondents reported long-term care insurance coverage in 1993. The question was changed in 1995, when respondents were asked, “Aside from the government programs, do you have any insurance which specifically pays any part of long-term care, such as personal or medical care in the home or in a nursing home?” This question, used in Finkelstein and McGarry (2006), generates a coverage rate of about 10 percent among adults ages 72 and older (up from 2 percent in the 1993 survey). However, this question also appears problematic, because many people are not well-informed about the nature of private long-term care insurance and may believe that they have coverage when in fact they do not. For example, a recent survey found that 31 percent of Americans ages 45 and older reported having private long-term care insurance (AARP 2001), an implausibly high figure given industry statistics. More than one-half of respondents believed that Medicare would cover extended nursing home stays. In 2002, the HRS survey first asked respondents follow-up questions about their reported private coverage, allowing researchers to identify respondents who mistakenly report Medicare and Medicaid as private long-term care insurance.

Perhaps most significant for our purposes, none of the existing studies provide a reliable estimate of the price elasticity of demand for private long-term care insurance coverage. To measure the potential impact of tax credits on the decision to purchase private coverage, we need to know how people will respond to a reduction in the after-tax premium. Although there are several estimates of price elasticities for general health insurance coverage (e.g., Gruber and Poterba 1994; Johnson, Moon, and Davidoff 2002; Marquis and Long 1995), there is little information on how changes in price affect the demand for long-term care insurance. Cramer and Jensen (2006) use recent high-quality data from the HRS to attempt to measure the price elasticity of demand for long-term care insurance, but their estimates are problematic. Of particular concern is their focus on the annual price while ignoring expected lifetime payouts. A 50-year-old woman, for example, faces lower annual premiums than a 70-year-old woman, but the younger policyholder surely recognizes that she will probably have to make many more annual payments before collecting benefits than the older woman. As a result, it is unclear how to interpret their findings on the relationship between take-up rates and annual premium payments, especially since the model does not control for the policyholder’s age.4

  TABLE III-1. Characteristics of Individual Long-Term Care Insurance Buyers, Nonbuyers, and the General Population Age 55 and Older, 2000  
  Sociodemographic Characteristic     Buyers     Nonbuyers     General Population  
ALL (%) 100 100 100
AGE
   Average (years) 67 71 69
   55-64 (%) 33 20 40
   65-69 (%) 27 23 16
   70-74 (%) 19 24 15
   75+ (%) 21 33 28
GENDER (%)
   Male 45 48 44
   Female 55 52 56
MARITAL STATUS (%)
   Never Married 4 3 4
   Married 70 67 57
   Divorced/Separated 6 9 8
   Widowed 20 21 33
INCOME STATUS (%)
   Less than $20,000 9 23 46 ($25,000)
   $20,000-$24,999 8 14
   $25,000-$34,999 19 22 14
   $35,000-$49,999 22 16 13
   $50,000+ 42 25 27
FINANCIAL ASSETS (%)
   Less than $20,000 6 19 60
   $20,000-$29,999 5 12 9
   $30,000-$49,999 7 11 10
   $50,000-$74,999 5 10 9
   $75,000-$99,999 6 6 6
   $100,000+ 71 42 7
EDUCATION (%)
   Not High School Graduate 5 9 27
   High School Graduate 21 28 36
   Post High School 27 27 18
   College Graduate 47 36 18
ANYONE IN HOUSEHOLD EMPLOYED? (%)
   Yes 35 17 31
   No 65 83 69
SOURCE: LifePlans, Inc. (2000).
TABLE III-2. Opinions About Long-Term Care Among Buyers and Nonbuyers of Individual Long-Term Care Insurance Age 55 and Over, 2000 (%)
  Buyers Nonbuyers
IT IS IMPORTANT TO PLAN NOW FOR THE POSSIBILITY OF NEEDING LONG-TERM CARE SERVICES:
   Strongly Agree/Agree 99 92
   Disagree/Strongly Disagree 1 8
I WORRY ABOUT HOW I WOULD PAY FOR CARE IF NEEDED:
   Strongly Agree/Agree 72 74
   Disagree/Strongly Disagree 29 26
THE INSURANCE INDUSTRY PROVIDES ADEQUATE COVERAGE FOR SERVICES:
   Strongly Agree/Agree 72 49
   Disagree/Strongly Disagree 28 51
IF I EVER NEEDED CARE, THE GOVERNMENT WOULD PAY MOST OF THE COSTS:
   Strongly Agree/Agree 15 33
   Disagree/Strongly Disagree 84 67
MOST IMPORTANT REASON FOR BUYING INDIVIDUAL LONG-TERM CARE INSURANCE
   Protect assets/leave an estate 31 NA
   Avoid dependence 19 NA
   Guarantee affordability 14 NA
   Protect living standards 12 NA
   Other 24 NA
MOST FREQUENTLY CITED REASON FOR NONPURCHASE OF INDIVIDUAL LONG-TERM CARE INSURANCE
   Too costly NA 54
   Waiting for better policy NA 29
   Hard to choose policy NA 18
   Don't believe insurers NA 15
SOURCE: LifePlans, Inc. (2000)

IV. METHODOLOGICAL APPROACH

There were two primary challenges in modeling the decision to purchase private long-term care insurance, particularly the effect of prices on coverage rates. First, at any age uncovered individuals who live in the same state generally face the same premiums, so it is difficult to observe how coverage rates vary with price, controlling for age and state of residence. Second, the premiums people face when considering private coverage depends on whether they purchased coverage in the past.

Covered adults who must decide each year whether to continue their coverage or let it lapse face lower premiums than uncovered adults. Annual premiums increase with age of initial purchase, but remain fixed over the life of the policy (unless unexpectedly large claims force the insurer to raise premiums for the entire class of policyholders). Consequently, in a simple equation that models coverage as a function of premiums, the error term is likely to be positively correlated with the premium, biasing upwards the estimated premium coefficient. Covered adults, who face lower premiums than uncovered adults, are probably more likely to purchase coverage by renewing their policies than uncovered adults, holding observable factors constant, because their prior purchase reveals their coverage preferences. Modeling coverage in a single year only for older people who have not already purchased is problematic, because these people have already revealed their reluctance to obtain private insurance.

The analysis addressed these complexities by estimating hazard models of time to purchase private long-term care insurance as a function of the net benefit that individuals expect to derive from the policy. The net expected benefit is the difference between what policyholders expect to receive in benefit payouts from the plan over their lifetimes, in present value terms, and what they expect to pay into the plan in the form of premiums.5 Individuals were dropped from the sample once they purchased coverage, eliminating the correlation between premiums and past purchase decisions. Observing purchase decisions over an extended period, beginning when respondents were relatively young, reduced the censoring problem that would otherwise result if we modeled only cases that had not yet purchased coverage at relatively old ages.

We can express the net expected benefit of purchasing private long-term care insurance as:

formula   , (1)  

where la,t is the probability of surviving from age a to age t, formula is the probability of surviving from age t to age f for someone who began using long-term care services at age t, pt is the probability that an individual who survives to age t uses long-term care services at that age, formula is the probability of having Medicaid coverage at age f for someone without private long-term care insurance who began using long-term care services at age t, formula is the probability of having Medicaid coverage at age f for someone with private long-term care insurance who began using long-term care services at age t, Sf,t is the cost of services used at age f for someone who began using services at age t, Xt is the maximum benefit payable by the policy at age t, Ct is the after-tax premium price at age t for someone who purchased a policy at age a, and d is the individual’s personal discount rate. The summation runs from current age a until T, the maximum lifespan.

The net expected benefit of private long-term care insurance coverage can be broken into three parts. The first term in equation (1) is the expected stream of lifetime payments for long-term care services if the individual does not purchase private insurance. We computed a different lifetime stream of expected payments for every age at which long-term care needs may start, multiplied each stream by the probability p that long-term care services start at that age, and summed these values. Each year that she uses long-term care services she has a chance mn of qualifying for Medicaid, which partly depends on how long she has been using services (and depleting her assets). If she qualifies, we assumed she pays nothing for the services she receives. If not, she pays the full cost of services out-of-pocket. Service intensity (and hence cost) in any year depends on when she first began receiving care.

The second and third terms are the expected lifetime stream of payments for an individual who purchases private long-term care insurance. The second term is the stream of out-of-pocket payments for services. As with the first term, the lifetime payment stream varies with the age at which long-term care needs begin, so we needed to compute separate probability-weighted streams for each possible age and sum them together. If the policyholder qualifies for Medicaid, she pays nothing. Otherwise, she pays only those costs that exceed the maximum benefit payable by the policy. The third term totals expected annual lifetime premiums paid by the policyholder. The plan we model requires policyholders to pay premiums only when they are not collecting benefits from the plan. Combining all three terms in equation (1), the net expected benefit of private long-term care insurance can be viewed as the difference between what uncovered older adults can expect to pay for lifetime services and what covered adults can expect to pay in premiums and payments for services that exceed the maximum payable benefits for their policies.

The net expected benefit computation ignores Medicare, which covers long-term care services only under certain circumstances. Medicare coverage of in-home care is restricted to skilled nursing care provided on a part-time or intermittent basis to homebound adults, and to personal care assistance provided by home health aides for those who are still receiving skilled care. It does not include homemaker services or personal care for people who do not receive skilled nursing care. For nursing home care, Medicare covers only short stays that follow hospitalizations.

The analysis examined the impact of the net expected benefit of private long-term care insurance on purchase decisions by including the measure as a regressor in a logit model of coverage. The data tracked individuals over time, and thus included multiple observations on each respondent. We excluded from the sample respondents with coverage at baseline, and observations on a given individual ceased when the individual purchased coverage or when the survey ended. Because the data were arranged in person-year format, the results can be interpreted as discrete-time hazard models (Allison 1984). We expected that the likelihood of purchasing coverage would increase with the expected net benefit. The model controlled for other factors likely to affect purchase decisions, including age, income, overall health status, education, marital status, gender, race, income, assets, number of children, and the self-assessed likelihood that the individual will someday enter a nursing home.

We used the model to simulate the likely impact of several policy levers on private coverage. We assessed tax incentives for long-term care insurance by recomputing the net expected benefit of coverage and using the model to measure the likely impact on take-up rates. We could also use the model to assess how various Medicaid reform options might affect coverage rates (although the present analysis is restricted to the potential impact of tax incentives).

V. DATA AND MEASURES

The primary data for our study came from the HRS, supplemented by data from several other sources to compute the net expected benefit of private coverage.

Health and Retirement Study

The HRS is a nationally representative longitudinal survey of older Americans that collects detailed information on health status, economic resources, demographic characteristics, family structure, and health insurance, including private long-term care insurance policies. Conducted by the University of Michigan with primary funding from the National Institute on Aging, the HRS began in 1992 with interviews of 9,814 adults born between 1931 and 1941, when they were ages 51-61. Respondents were reinterviewed every other year. The HRS began interviewing other cohorts after 1992. In 1993 the survey added adults born before 1924 to the sampling frame and in 1998 it added adults born between 1924 and 1930 and those born between 1942 and 1947.6 In 2002, then, the HRS sample consisted of Americans ages 55 and older. The most recent survey data are from 2004.

Rates of private long-term care insurance coverage in the later waves of the HRS seem reasonable. The survey asks respondents whether they have any long-term care insurance (excluding government programs) that cover nursing home care for a year or more or some at-home personal or medical care. Follow-up questions added in 2002 (and repeated in subsequent years) ask whether the respondent had already described the plan to the interviewer, such as when reporting traditional health insurance plans, and if so to identify the plan. We reclassified respondents as not having private long-term care insurance if they said that their private long-term care insurance policies were Medicaid, Medicare, or traditional health plans. This recoding reduced the share of respondents ages 55 and older with private coverage in 2002 from 11.4 percent to 9.1 percent, dropping population estimates (based on the HRS sample weights) from 6.99 million to 5.41 million. AHIP (2004) estimated that the cumulative number of long-term care insurance policies sold reached 9.2 million in 2002. Approximately 72 percent, or 6.60 million, remained in force in 2002. The lower HRS estimate covers only the older population, which holds many, but not all, of the long-term care policies in force.

The profile of private long-term care insurance purchasers in the HRS is similar to the profile of buyers reported by LifePlans, Inc. (2000). Table V-1 compares the characteristics of new long-term care insurance purchasers in the 2000 and 2002 HRS and those in the LifePlans, Inc. study of long-term care insurance buyers and nonbuyers ages 55 and older in 2000.7 The HRS buyers (especially in 2000) were quite similar to the LifePlans buyers in terms of age, gender, marital status, and the presence of an employed adult in the household. Although the average age of purchasers was lower in the 2002 HRS sample than in the other samples, this decline may reflect an increase over time in the purchase of group coverage, which tends to attract younger enrollees than individual plans. Purchasers in the 2000 HRS had somewhat less education than those in the LifePlans sample, although average educational attainment was similar for the 2002 HRS buyers and the LifePlans buyers.

Income and wealth differ substantially between the HRS and LifePlans samples. In 2000, the HRS sample included more buyers with incomes over $50,000 (52 percent) than the LifePlans sample (42 percent). And the differences widen in the 2002 sample. At the same time, the HRS buyers were more likely to hold financial assets worth less than $20,000 (29 percent) than the LifePlans sample (6 percent). These differences largely remain in the 2002 sample. Differences in the income and assets distributions could arise for a couple of reasons. First, the LifePlans data reflect individual long-term care insurance purchasers only, not group market purchasers. Group purchasers may have higher incomes than individual purchasers because they are more likely to be employed. They may also have lower assets because they tend to be younger. Second, the LifePlans and HRS surveys may use different definitions of income and wealth.

HRS data indicate that 9.0 percent of noninstitutionalized adults ages 55 and older had private long-term care insurance coverage in 2002 (Table V-2). Coverage rates were somewhat lower at ages 55-64 (7.3 percent), and somewhat higher at ages 65-74 (10.7 percent). Rates increased rapidly with education and health status. For example, 12.2 percent of older adults who described their health as excellent or very good reported coverage, compared with only 4.5 percent of those in fair or poor health. Only about 3 percent of those who did not complete high school had coverage, compared with 17 percent of college graduates. Rates were also higher among Whites than African Americans and Hispanics, and higher among married adults than those who were divorced or widowed. Women were somewhat more likely to report coverage than men.

Coverage rates in the HRS also increased with income and assets (Table V-3). About 15 percent of adults ages 55 and older in the top quartile of the household income distribution reported coverage in 2002, compared with only about 3 percent of those in the bottom quartile and about 7 percent of those in the second quartile. Similarly, about 18 percent of adults ages 55 and older in the top quartile of the distribution of household net worth (consisting of the value of financial assets, housing, and other real assets) reported private long-term care insurance coverage in 2002. By comparison, only about 2 percent of those in the bottom quartile of the household net worth distribution, and 5 percent of those in the second quartile reported private long-term care insurance.

For our analysis we used data on respondents in the original HRS cohort (ages 51-61 when first interviewed in 1992) who responded to the 2002 survey. The 2002 and 2004 surveys asked covered respondents when they purchased their long-term care insurance polices, and asked uncovered respondents if they had ever purchased long-term care insurance. We used this information to determine purchase decisions before 2002, because the earlier survey questions were less reliable. However, we did use the earlier survey responses for the relatively few respondents without insurance in 2002 who reported having had coverage in the past, because the 2002 survey did not ask those with lapsed policies when they first purchased them.

Computing the Net Expected Benefit of Coverage

As described in the previous chapter, the net expected benefit of private long-term care insurance coverage depends on how much people pay for private insurance after taxes, expected usage of long-term care services, expected cost of services in the absence of private insurance, and the likelihood of qualifying for Medicaid. The expected present value calculations assumed a personal discount rate of 3 percent, inflation rate of 3 percent, and real wage growth of 1 percent. They also assumed that future real tax rates equal the rates that prevailed in 2004 and that mortality expectations were consistent with the Robinson model of long-term care use, described in detail later in the chapter.

Long-Term Care Insurance Premiums. We obtained premium information from Weiss Ratings, Inc., a private insurance rating firm in Jupiter, FL. They provided us with average premiums by state and issue age, based on a 2003 survey of 26 insurers.8 The premiums were for plans that provided coverage for nursing home, assisted living facility, home health, and community-based care, with a 20-90 day elimination period, 3-6 year benefit period, $100 daily benefit, and inflation protection. We deflated premiums for earlier years and inflated them for 2004 by the change in the national average daily private-pay rate for a semi-private room in a nursing home (Metlife various years).

Table V-4 reports 2002 premiums by state and selected issue age. They increased rapidly with age and varied by state. For example, in New York the average premium increased from $748 when issued at age 55, to $1,358 at age 65, to $3,252 at age 75. At issue age 65, average premiums ranged from a low of $1,256 in Massachusetts to a high of $1,602 in Florida.

After-Tax Premiums. Some policyholders are able to lower the after-tax price of private long-term care insurance by deducting premium payments from income subject to federal and state taxes. The federal tax code considers a portion of premium payments for qualified long-term care insurance policies as medical expenses, so they are deductible from taxable income to the extent that total medical expenses exceed 7.5 percent of adjusted gross income. However, the amount of premiums that can be deducted is capped. In 2002, the maximum annual premium deduction was $240 at ages 40 and younger, $450 at ages 41-50, $900 at ages 51-60, $2,390 at ages 61-70, and $2,990 at ages 71 and older.

Many states also provide special tax breaks for private long-term care insurance. For example, some states provide tax credits for premiums expenses, up to certain limits expressed either as a share of premiums or a dollar amount. Other states allow taxpayers to deduct their premiums from their taxable income. Table V-5 reports the availability of state income tax breaks for private long-term care insurance in each of the states.

We estimated after-tax premiums by subtracting from premiums the reduction in federal and state tax liabilities that people can realize from purchasing long-term care insurance coverage. We estimated federal and state tax liabilities by applying the detailed tax calculator developed by Jon Bakija at Williams College. HRS collects information on all sources of income. It also provides information on family structure and most types of deductible expenses, including out-of-pocket medical expenses, charitable donations, property taxes, and outstanding mortgage debt, but not mortgage interest payments. We set mortgage interest payments equal to 6 percent of the outstanding mortgage. The tax calculator estimated state tax liabilities, which taxpayers who itemize their deductions can also deduct from taxable income. We assumed that respondents claimed as dependents all children ages 18 or younger and children ages 19-23 attending school. The tax calculator selected which taxpayers itemized their deductions and which married taxpayers filed jointly so as to minimize tax liabilities.

Expected Use of Long-Term Care Services. Our estimates of expected long-term care usage were based on a transition model of different care states developed by Jim Robinson of the University of Wisconsin, a former member of the SOA's Long-Term Care Insurance Valuation Methods Task Force. The model uses data from the 1985 National Nursing Home Survey and the 1982-1994 waves of the National Long-Term Care Survey to produce estimates of age and gender-specific Markov transition probabilities across four different care states: no care, home care, nursing home, and death. (The original model also modeled transitions into and out of assisted living.)

The model implies that a 65-year-old woman has a 44 percent chance of using a nursing home sometime in the future and that a 65-year-old man stands a 27 percent chance. On average, institutionalized women spend 1.3 years in nursing homes, and men spend 2.0 years. These estimates are comparable to other estimates in the literature (Dick, Garber, and MaCurdy 1994; Kemper and Murtaugh 1991; Murtaugh et al. 1997; Spillman and Lubitz 2002; Wiener, Illston, and Hanley 1994).

Expected Cost of Long-Term Care Services. We estimated the expected cost of future long-term care services in the absence of private insurance by multiplying expected usage by private-pay rates for nursing home care and home health care, which vary by state. The average daily pay rate for nursing home care (excluding therapy, rehabilitation, and medication costs) came from a national survey by the long-term care division of GE Financial (AARP various years). Home health care costs equaled the hourly price charged by an agency for a home health aide, based on a survey of 521 agencies (MetLife various years).

Table V-6 shows 2002 nursing home and home health costs by state. Daily nursing home costs range from a high of $448 in Alaska and $256 in Connecticut, to a low of $99 in Louisiana. Hourly home health care costs range from a high of $27 in Alaska and $23 in Connecticut to a low of $13 in Alabama, Louisiana, and Mississippi.

After 2004, expected real nursing home and home health care costs increased at the same rate as real wages, assumed to be 1 percent per year.

Medicaid Eligibility Rules. Medicaid pays for nursing home and home care services for disabled older adults with limited income and virtually no assets. Eligibility rules are complex and vary by state. Table V-7 summarizes Medicaid eligibility rules for institutionalized individuals, and Table V-8 summarizes eligibility rules for home and community-based care for older adults.

In most states, aged or disabled adults who receive Supplemental Security Income (SSI) automatically qualify for Medicaid. In 2002, the federal SSI limits for individuals were $545 per month in countable income and $2,000 in countable assets. (For couples, the monthly limits were $817 in income and $3,000 in assets). Some states impose even more stringent limits for Medicaid participation, corresponding to the eligibility rules for cash assistance programs for the aged and disabled in place before the introduction of the SSI program in 1972. Countable assets generally exclude the value of owner-occupied housing, an automobile used to obtain medical treatment, certain burial funds, and up to $2,000 in personal effects.

Individuals who do not qualify for SSI may still generally receive long-term care services through Medicaid. Federal regulations allow state Medicaid programs to pay for long-term care services for individuals with incomes up to 300 percent of the federal SSI benefit (or $1,656 per month in 2003). The "300 percent rule" for nursing home care exists in 31 states, and another four states use income thresholds for Medicaid-financed nursing home care that are between 100 percent and 300 percent of the federal SSI benefit (Bruen, Wiener, and Thomas 2003). In a few states, an individual may have more than $2,000 in assets and still qualify for long-term care services. Most states apply the same limits to determine eligibility for home and community-based services.

Individuals with incomes too high to qualify for long-term care services may "spend-down" to Medicaid eligibility and receive benefits. In fact, about one-third of discharged nursing home residents admitted as private-pay residents had spent down to Medicaid by the time of their discharge (Wiener, Sullivan, and Skaggs 1996). Most state Medicaid programs include medically needy provisions, which exclude medical and long-term care expenses from income when determining program eligibility. However, the income thresholds in medically needy cases are lower than the SSI income thresholds. Medicaid applicants who live in states that do not offer medically needy programs and whose pension and Social Security incomes exceed the Medicaid eligibility standards can still qualify for long-term care services by assigning their incomes to special trusts, called Qualified Income trusts or Miller trusts. These trusts release to the applicants income equal to one dollar less than the income eligibility threshold and directs the remainder of the payment to the facility or care provider.

Medicaid pays for long-term care services only after eligible users have exhausted almost all of their resources on their long-term care costs. Aside from income they may protect for a community-dwelling spouse, Medicaid nursing home residents may keep only a small personal needs allowance. By federal law, this allowance must be at least $30 per month, and may not exceed $90 per month. Participants in waiver programs that provide home and community-based services may keep substantially more of their income to cover the expense of living in the community. The maintenance needs allowance, as it is called, varies by state, ranging from 100 percent to 300 percent of the SSI benefit amount (Bruen, Wiener, and Thomas 2003).

Medicaid law requires states to protect the income and assets of spouses of Medicaid nursing home residents. Community-dwelling spouses are entitled to all of the income received in their own names and half of the income they receive jointly with their spouses, plus half of the value of assets held by both spouses combined. However, states must also establish minimum levels of assets and income that the community spouses can keep even if their resource shares fall short of these levels. The minimum monthly income allowance for spouses must be at least 150 percent of the federal poverty level for couples (or $1,493 in 2002), while the minimum asset allowance in 2002 is $17,865. States can raise minimum allowances for spouses, but they cannot exceed $2,232 in monthly income or $89,324 in assets (in 2002).

Estimating Medicaid Eligibility. We combined state eligibility rules, income and asset data, assumptions about growth in financial resources over time, and expected long-term care costs to predict whether individuals could expect Medicaid to cover any future long-term care expenses in the absence of private insurance coverage. We assumed that income grew at a 1 percent real rate until age 65, the assumed retirement age for everyone still working in the baseline sample. (We assumed that people still working after age 65 in the baseline sample retired the next year.). At retirement, we set income equal to 70 percent of pre-retirement income, a typical replacement rate for retirees (Uccello 2001), and assumed it remained constant in real terms until death. We assumed that real income remained constant throughout for those already retired at baseline. Spousal earnings and retirement benefits are lost when the spouse dies. Spousal mortality expectations were based on life tables developed by the Social Security Administration.

The analysis also projected asset levels as people age. We assumed that assets grew until age 65 at a real rate of 2.31 percent per year for single people and 2.77 percent per year for married people (Johnson, Mermin, and Uccello 2006). Assets were assumed to remain constant in real terms after age 65, until people developed long-term care needs and began depleting their wealth to pay nursing home and home care bills. We estimated asset spend-down based on expected use and cost of long-term care services, as described earlier.

Other Measures

In addition to the net expected benefit of coverage, the probit models controlled for age, overall health status, education, marital status, gender, race, total household income, total household assets, number of children ages 22 and older, number of children younger than age 22, and the self-assessed probability of future nursing home use. Respondents ages 65 and older were asked the percent chance that they would move to a nursing home in the next five years. However, because the survey did not ask this question of respondents younger than age 65, the variable is missing for many observations. When the information was missing, we set the variable equal to zero and set a missing variable indicator equal to one. Household assets included the value of the home, other real assets, and financial assets.

Sample Characteristics

The sample consisted of person-year observations between 1992 and 2004 on adults ages 51-61 in 1992 who did not have coverage in the previous year. We observed respondents every other year. We restricted our sample to respondents likely to satisfy long-term care insurers' underwriting restrictions and thus able to purchase private coverage. We dropped respondents who reported any ADL or IADL limitations, kidney problems, history of stroke, or cognitive impairment, and who were not living in nursing homes. In 1992, about 5 percent of respondents were dropped from the sample because they reported one of these health problems. The share increased over time as the sample aged, rising to 32 percent in 2002. Overall, 17 percent of the person-year observations were dropped because of health problems or nursing home residence. The final sample consisted of 32,242 observations on 6,991 respondents.

Table V-9 reports descriptive statistics of variables used in the models. The average age of the sample was 60, mean household income was about $74,000, and mean household assets was about $413,000. About 14 percent of respondents reported purchasing private long-term care insurance during the observation period, but only 2 percent of the sample reported coverage because individuals were dropped from the sample after they purchased private insurance coverage. The mean present discounted value of expected lifetime out-of-pocket payments for long-term care services was about $68,800 for those without private insurance. On average, respondents who purchased private insurance they could expect to pay lifetime premiums of about $32,600 and make out-of-pocket payments for services of about the same amount, in present discounted value terms. The mean net expected benefit of coverage, then, amounted to about $3,600.

TABLE V-1. Buyer Profiles, Age 55 and Older, 2000 and 2002
  Personal Characteristics     LifePlans Buyer Study  2000 HRS
  2000  (All)   2002  (All) 2002  (Unique Policy)  
ALL (%) 100 100 100 100
AGE
   Average (years) 67 67 65 64
   55-64 (%) 33 43 56 58
   65-69 (%) 27 24 22 21
   70-74 (%) 19 16 13 13
   75+ (%) 21 17 9 8
GENDER (%)
   Male 45 44 43 46
   Female 55 56 57 54
MARITAL STATUS (%)
   Never Married 4 3 2 3
   Married 70 73 79 82
   Divorced/Separated 6 7 9 7
   Widowed 20 17 10 8
INCOME STATUS (%)
   Less than $20,000 9 11 8 5
   $20,000-$24,999 8 8 5 5
   $25,000-$34,999 19 12 10 9
   $35,000-$49,999 22 17 13 13
   $50,000+ 42 52 65 69
FINANCIAL ASSETS (%)
   Less than $20,000 6 29 29 25
   $20,000-$29,999 5 5 4 4
   $30,000-$49,999 7 8 6 7
   $50,000-$74,999 5 5 9 8
   $75,000-$99,999 6 7 7 9
   $100,000+ 71 46 44 48
EDUCATION (%)
   Not High School Graduate 5 12 9 7
   High School Graduate 21 32 26 26
   Post High School 27 24 19 18
   College Graduate 47 32 45 49
ANYONE IN HOUSEHOLD EMPLOYED? (%)
   Yes 35 38 47 48
   No 65 62 53 52
SOURCE: LifePlans, Inc. (2000); Urban Institute tabulations from the 2000 and 2002 HRS.
TABLE V-2. Share of Noninstitutionalized Population Age 55 and Older with Given Characteristic and Share with Private Long-Term Care Insurance Coverage, 2002 (%)
  Share with  Given Characteristic   Share with Private  Long-Term Care Insurance  
ALL 100.0 9.0
AGE
   55-64 43.3 7.3
   65-74 30.4 10.7
   75 and older 26.3 9.6
GENDER
   Male 44.4 8.6
   Female 55.6 9.3
MARITAL STATUS
   Never Married 3.4 8.4
   Married 63.9 10.2
   Divorced/Separated 12.0 5.0
   Widowed 20.7 7.5
RACE
   African American 8.9 2.0
   Hispanic 6.4 0.9
   White, Other 84.7 10.3
EDUCATION
   Not High School Graduate 22.6 3.1
   High School Graduate 52.9 8.2
   Some College 3.7 10.4
   4+ Years of College 20.8 17.0
HEALTH STATUS
   Excellent or Very Good 41.9 12.2
   Good 31.6 8.4
   Fair or Poor 26.5 4.5
NUMBER OF ADL LIMITATIONS
   0 83.6 9.6
   1 7.9 8.2
   2 3.6 4.3
   3 2.1 3.0
   4 or More 2.7 1.8
SOURCE: Urban Institute tabulations from the 2002 HRS. NOTE: Estimates are based on sample of 16,709 noninstitutionalized adults ages 55 and older. The analysis considers respondents to have private long-term insurance coverage only if they report coverage distinct from their traditional health insurance plan.
TABLE V-3. Share of Noninstitutionalized Population Age 55 and Older with Private Long-Term Care Insurance Coverage, by Economic Status and Age, 2002 (%)
  55 and Older 55-64 65-74 75 and Older
HOUSEHOLD INCOME QUARTILE
   Bottom 2.8 2.2 3.0 2.5
   Second 7.3 5.2 8.2 6.6
   Third 11.3 7.4 14.2 10.4
   Top 14.5 14.5 17.6 19.1
HOUSEHOLD NET WORTH QUARTILE
   Bottom 1.6 1.3 1.3 2.3
   Second 4.6 3.3 6.0 5.6
   Third 11.4 9.3 14.2 11.7
   Top 18.2 15.4 21.3 18.9
HOUSEHOLD FINANCIAL ASSETS QUARTILE
   Bottom 2.1 1.8 3.6 1.4
   Second 6.2 4.7 5.9 7.4
   Third 9.6 8.8 12.3 10.2
   Top 18.0 14.1 21.4 19.5
HOUSEHOLD INCOME QUARTILE
   Bottom 1.4 1.0 1.7 1.2
   Second 5.2 4.9 5.5 5.7
   Third 10.5 7.2 13.8 12.3
   Top 18.8 16.1 21.9 19.3
SOURCE: Urban Institute tabulations from the 2002 HRS. NOTE: Estimates are based on sample of 16,709 noninstitutionalized adults ages 55 and older. The analysis considers respondents to have private long-term insurance coverage only if they report coverage distinct from their traditional health insurance plan. Income and wealth are adjusted for household size by dividing values for married respondents by 1.62, the midpoint of the range of household equivalence scales recommended by the National Academy of Science (Citro and Michael 1995). Household net worth includes the value of housing, bank accounts, stocks, bonds, other real estate, IRAs, vehicles, and businesses, net of mortgage and other debt. Household nonhousing wealth equals household net worth minus the value of the primary residence and any outstanding mortgage. Financial assets consist of bank accounts, stocks, and bonds. Quartiles are computed separately for each age group.
TABLE V-4. Average Annual Premiums in the Individual Long-Term Care Insurance Market, by State and Selected Issue Age, 2002 ($)
State   55     60     65     70     75  
Alabama 789 1,048 1,470 2,257 3,611
Alaska 856 1,119 1,541 2,324 3,681
Arizona 762 1,018 1,424 2,186 3,490
Arkansas 763 1,021 1,427 2,193 3,494
California 736 987 1,399 2,183 3,629
Colorado 780 1,020 1,396 2,125 3,363
Connecticut 808 1,063 1,467 2,218 3,525
Delaware 785 1,039 1,461 2,245 3,585
District of Columbia   825 1,086 1,497 2,269 3,572
Florida 865 1,143 1,602 2,462 3,936
Georgia 766 1,033 1,451 2,232 3,593
Hawaii 822 1,086 1,527 2,348 3,751
Idaho 785 1,044 1,458 2,234 3,574
IIllinois 752 992 1,390 2,135 3,419
Indiana 741 990 1,392 2,128 3,376
Iowa 773 1,020 1,407 2,144 3,399
Kansas 775 1,028 1,439 2,211 3,534
Kentucky 771 1,033 1,443 2,221 3,551
Louisiana 759 1,014 1,418 2,180 3,468
Maine 818 1,073 1,487 2,262 3,566
Maryland 696 925 1,326 2,076 3,397
Massachusetts 689 917 1,256 1,913 3,022
Michigan 769 1,031 1,449 2,224 3,552
Minnesota 730 971 1,378 2,122 3,460
Mississippi 769 1,026 1,437 2,211 3,525
Missouri 765 1,012 1,414 2,172 3,466
Montana 761 991 1,385 2,129 3,410
Nebraska 764 1,008 1,411 2,168 3,460
Nevada 764 1,022 1,428 2,193 3,500
New Hampshire 825 1,096 1,518 2,299 3,612
New Jersey 798 1,064 1,499 2,266 3,684
New Mexico 772 1,033 1,442 2,214 3,531
New York 748 999 1,358 2,061 3,252
North Carolina 779 1,048 1,469 2,259 3,609
North Dakota 778 1,022 1,425 2,187 3,475
Ohio 761 1,006 1,410 2,163 3,430
Oklahoma 751 993 1,390 2,134 3,404
Oregon 779 1,033 1,441 2,216 3,533
Pennsylvania 724 969 1,376 2,134 3,416
Rhode Island 770 1,027 1,450 2,232 3,581
South Carolina 774 1,041 1,461 2,246 3,593
South Dakota 775 1,018 1,423 2,189 3,502
Tennessee 764 1,023 1,429 2,197 3,508
Texas 731 950 1,338 2,060 3,290
Utah 781 1,036 1,428 2,167 3,415
Vermont 834 1,093 1,511 2,297 3,615
Virginia 744 1,019 1,438 2,214 3,515
Washington 804 1,074 1,501 2,306 3,700
West Virginia 801 1,069 1,499 2,307 3,700
Wisconsin 779 1,054 1,480 2,274 3,686
Wyoming 764 1,022 1,428 2,193 3,500
SOURCE: Urban Institute tabulations of Weiss Ratings, Inc. data. NOTE: Premiums were for plans that provided coverage for nursing home, assisted living facility, home health, and community-based care, with a 20-90 day elimination period, 3-6 year benefit period, $100 daily benefit, and inflation protection.
TABLE V-5. State Income Tax Deductions and Credits for Private Long-Term Care Insurance, 2002
State Maximum Tax Credit Tax Deduction
  Dollar Amount     Share of  Premium   Deduction Available     Deduction Requires  Itemization
Alabama --- --- Yes Yes
Alaska --- --- --- ---
Arizona --- --- Yesa Yes
Arkansas --- --- --- ---
California --- --- --- ---
Colorado 150 25% --- ---
Connecticut --- --- --- ---
Delaware --- --- --- ---
District of Columbia   --- --- --- ---
Florida --- --- --- ---
Georgia --- --- --- ---
Hawaii --- --- --- ---
Idaho --- --- Yesb ---
IIllinois --- --- --- ---
Indiana --- --- Yesc ---
Iowa --- --- Yes ---
Kansas --- --- --- ---
Kentucky --- --- Yes ---
Louisiana --- --- --- ---
Maine --- --- Yesd ---
Maryland 500e 100%e --- ---
Massachusetts --- --- --- ---
Michigan --- --- --- ---
Minnesota 100 25% --- ---
Mississippi --- --- --- ---
Missouri --- --- --- ---
Montana --- --- Yes Yes
Nebraska --- --- --- ---
Nevada --- --- --- ---
New Hampshire --- --- --- ---
New Jersey --- --- Yesa ---
New Mexico --- --- Yesa ---
New York --- 10% --- ---
North Carolina 350 15% --- ---
North Dakota 100 25% --- ---
Ohio --- --- Yes ---
Oklahoma --- --- --- ---
Oregon 500 15% --- ---
Pennsylvania --- --- --- ---
Rhode Island --- --- --- ---
South Carolina --- --- --- ---
South Dakota --- --- --- ---
Tennessee --- --- --- ---
Texas --- --- --- ---
Utah --- --- Yesc ---
Vermont --- --- --- ---
Virginia --- --- Yesc Yes
Washington --- --- --- ---
West Virginia --- --- Yesc ---
Wisconsin --- --- Yesc ---
Wyoming --- --- --- ---
SOURCE: Urban Institute analysis of state tax laws and AARP Public Policy Institute. See http://www.aarp.org/bulletin/longterm/a2003-06-23-taxincentives-.html. NOTES:
  1. Available as a deductible medical expense. Medical expense limits (if any) apply.
  2. Taxpayers may deduct 50% of portion not deducted on their federal income tax returns.
  3. Taxpayers may deduct the portion not deducted on their federal income tax returns.
  4. Policy must meet the definition of a qualified long-term care contract or must be certified by Maine Bureau of Insurance.
  5. Tax credits are available only in the year in which the policy is first purchased.
TABLE V-6. Average Nursing Costs and Home Health Care Costs, by State, 2002 ($)
State   Daily Nursing  Home Costs Hourly Home  Health Care Costs  
Alabama 123 13
Alaska 448 27
Arizona 162 18
Arkansas 105 14
California 166 18
Colorado 140 22
Connecticut 256 23
Delaware 160 19
District of Columbia   241 16
Florida 153 15
Georgia 114 17
Hawaii 238 19
Idaho 144 16
IIllinois 136 18
Indiana 142 19
Iowa 119 18
Kansas 111 17
Kentucky 139 19
Louisiana 99 13
Maine 186 18
Maryland 164 15
Massachusetts 222 21
Michigan 157 17
Minnesota 157 22
Mississippi 118 13
Missouri 112 17
Montana 128 15
Nebraska 138 19
Nevada 165 20
New Hampshire 190 21
New Jersey 222 18
New Mexico 159 17
New York 247 17
North Carolina 146 17
North Dakota 174 18
Ohio 150 16
Oklahoma 110 16
Oregon 160 17
Pennsylvania 187 18
Rhode Island 190 20
South Carolina 127 15
South Dakota 131 14
Tennessee 127 15
Texas 115 18
Utah 131 20
Vermont 182 17
Virginia 139 16
Washington 175 19
West Virginia 136 16
Wisconsin 148 21
Wyoming 147 15
SOURCE: AARP (2002) and MetLife (2002).
TABLE V-7. Medicaid Eligibility Standards, Personal Needs Allowance, and Spousal Impoverishment Resource Limits for Institutionalized Individuals, by State, 2001/2002
State Income Threshold Asset Threshold   Spousal Protection     Medically Needy  Provision
  Single     Couple     Single     Couple  
Alabama 1,635 2,451 2,000 3,000 25,000 ---
Alaska 1,635 2,451 2,000 3,000 87,000 ---
Arizona 1,635 2,451 2,000 3,000 17,400 ---
Arkansas 1,635 2,451 2,000 3,000 87,000 Yes
California 738 995 2,000 3,000 87,000 Yes
Colorado 1,635 2,451 2,000 3,000 87,000 ---
Connecticut 1,635 2,451 1,600 2,400 17,400 Yes
Delaware 1,363 2,043 2,000 3,000 87,000 ---
District of Columbia   738 995 2,600 3,000 17,400 Yes
Florida 1,635 2,451 5,000 6,000 87,000 Yes
Georgia 1,635 2,451 2,000 4,000 87,000 Yes
Hawaii 1,145 1,145 2,000 3,000 87,000 Yes
Idaho 1,635 2,451 2,000 3,000 17,400 ---
IIllinois 2,985 2,985 2,000 3,000 87,000 Yes
Indiana 817 817 1,500 1,500 17,400 ---
Iowa 1,635 2,451 10,000 10,000 24,000 Yes
Kansas 1,635 2,451 2,000 3,000 17,400 Yes
Kentucky 1,635 2,451 2,000 4,000 87,000 Yes
Louisiana 1,635 2,451 2,000 3,000 87,000 Yes
Maine 1,635 2,451 2,000 3,000 87,000 Yes
Maryland 1,635 2,451 2,500 3,000 87,000 Yes
Massachusetts 738 995 2,000 3,000 87,000 Yes
Michigan 1,635 2,451 2,000 3,000 87,000 Yes
Minnesota 1,635 2,451 3,000 6,000 24,247 Yes
Mississippi 1,635 2,451 2,000 6,000 87,000 ---
Missouri 976 1,462 999.99 2,000 17,400 ---
Montana 525 525 2,000 3,000 17,400 Yes
Nebraska 738 995 4,000 6,000 17,400 Yes
Nevada 1,635 2,451 2,000 3,000 87,000 ---
New Hampshire 1,286 1,928 2,500 4,000 17,400 Yes
New Jersey 1,635 2,451 4,000 6,000 17,400 Yes
New Mexico 1,635 2,451 2,000 3,000 31,290 ---
New York 625 900 3,750 5,400 74,820 Yes
North Carolina 738 995 2,000 3,000 17,400 Yes
North Dakota 796 796 3,000 6,000 87,000 Yes
Ohio 796 796 1,500 1,500 17,400 ---
Oklahoma 1,635 2,451 2,000 3,000 17,400 Yes
Oregon 1,635 2,451 2,000 3,000 17,400 Yes
Pennsylvania 1,635 2,451 2,400 3,200 17,400 Yes
Rhode Island 1,635 2,451 4,000 6,000 17,400 Yes
South Carolina 1,635 2,451 2,000 3,000 66,480 ---
South Dakota 1,635 2,451 2,000 3,000 20,000 ---
Tennessee 1,635 2,451 2,000 3,000 17,400 Yes
Texas 1,635 2,451 2,000 3,000 17,400 ---
Utah 1,635 2,451 2,000 3,000 17,400 Yes
Vermont 1,472 2,206 2,000 3,000 87,000 Yes
Virginia 1,635 2,451 2,000 3,000 87,000 Yes
Washington 1,635 2,451 2,000 3,000 87,000 Yes
West Virginia 1,635 2,451 2,000 3,000 87,000 Yes
Wisconsin 1,635 2,451 2,000 3,000 50,000 Yes
Wyoming 1,635 2,451 2,000 3,000 87,000 ---
SOURCE: Bruen, Wiener, and Thomas (2003).
  TABLE V-8. Medicaid Eligibility Rules for Home and Community-Based Care for Aged Adults, by State, 2001/2002  
State Income Threshold Asset Threshold Spend-Down/  Miller Trust Avail.   Spousal  Impoverishment  
  Single     Couple     Single     Couple  
Alabama 545 817 2,000 3,000 --- ---
Alaska 1,635 2,451 2,000 3,000 Yes Yes
Arizona 1,635 2,451 2,000 3,000 Yes Yes
Arkansas 1,635 2,451 2,000 3,000 Yes ---
California 982 1,323 2,000 3,000 Yes Yes
Colorado 1,635 2,451 2,000 3,000 Yes ---
Connecticut 1,635 2,451 1,600 2,400 --- Yes
Delaware 1,363 2,043 2,000 3,000 Yes Yes
District of Columbia   738 995 2,600 3,000 Yes ---
Florida 1,635 2,451 5,000 6,000 Yes Yes
Georgia 1,635 2,451 2,000 4,000 --- Yes
Hawaii 850 995 2,000 3,000 Yes Yes
Idaho 1,635 2,451 2,000 3,000 Yes Yes
IIllinois 627 846 2,000 3,000 --- Yes
Indiana 1,635 2,451 1,500 1,500 --- Yes
Iowa 1,635 2,451 10,000 10,000 Yes Yes
Kansas 1,635 2,451 2,000 3,000 Yes Yes
Kentucky 1,635 2,451 2,000 4,000 --- Yes
Louisiana 1,635 2,451 2,000 3,000 --- Yes
Maine 2,214 2,985 2,000 3,000 --- ---
Maryland 1,635 2,451 2,500 3,000 --- Yes
Massachusetts 738 995 2,000 3,000 --- ---
Michigan 1,635 2,451 2,000 3,000 Yes ---
Minnesota 1,635 2,451 3,000 6,000 Yes Yes
Mississippi 1,635 2,451 2,000 3,000 Yes Yes
Missouri 976 1,462 1,000 1,000 Yes Yes
Montana 525 525 2,000 3,000 --- ---
Nebraska 738 995 4,000 6,000 --- Yes
Nevada 1,635 2,451 2,000 3,000 Yes ---
New Hampshire 1,635 2,451 2,500 4,000 --- ---
New Jersey 1,635 2,451 4,000 6,000 --- Yes
New Mexico 1,635 2,451 2,000 3,000 --- Yes
New York 625 625 3,750 5,400 --- Yes
North Carolina 738 995 2,000 3,000 --- Yes
North Dakota 475 475 3,000 6,000 --- ---
Ohio 460 460 1,500 1,500 --- Yes
Oklahoma 1,635 2,451 2,000 3,000 Yes Yes
Oregon 1,635 2,451 2,000 3,000 Yes Yes
Pennsylvania 1,635 2,451 2,400 3,200 --- ---
Rhode Island 1,635 2,451 4,000 6,000 Yes Yes
South Carolina 1,635 2,451 2,000 3,000 Yes Yes
South Dakota 1,635 2,451 2,000 3,000 Yes Yes
Tennessee 1,635 2,451 2,000 3,000 --- Yes
Texas 1,635 2,451 2,000 3,000 Yes Yes
Utah 1,635 2,451 2,000 3,000 Yes Yes
Vermont 1,635 2,451 2,000 3,000 Yes Yes
Virginia 1,635 2,451 2,000 3,000 Yes Yes
Washington 1,635 2,451 2,000 3,000 --- Yes
West Virginia 1,635 2,451 2,000 3,000 --- Yes
Wisconsin 1,635 2,451 2,000 3,000 --- Yes
Wyoming 1,635 2,451 2,000 3,000 Yes Yes
SOURCE: Bruen, Wiener, and Thomas (2003).
TABLE V-9. Descriptive Statistics of Variables in Logit Models
Variable   Mean     Standard Error  
SHARE OF OBSERVATIONS WITH LONG-TERM CARE INSURANCE COVERAGE 0.022 0.001
NET EXPECTED BENEFIT OF COVERAGE ($1,000) 3.623 0.114
PDV OF LIFETIME PREMIUM PAYMENTS ($1,000) 32.589 0.060
PDV OF OUT-OF-POCKET PAYMENTS WITHOUT PRIVATE INSURANCE ($1,000) 68.807 0.195
PDV OF OUT-OF-POCKET PAYMENTS WITH PRIVATE INSURANCE ($1,000) 32.595 0.122
AGE 60.0 0.028
HEALTH STATUS
   Excellent or Very Good 0.556 0.003
   Good 0.302 0.003
   Fair or Poor 0.141 0.002
EDUCATION
   Less than High School 0.206 0.002
   High School Graduate 0.374 0.003
   Post High School 0.203 0.002
   College Graduate 0.217 0.003
MARRIED 0.758 0.003
FEMALE 0.536 0.003
RACE
   African American 0.084 0.001
   Hispanic 0.056 0.001
   White, Other 0.860 0.002
HOUSEHOLD INCOME ($10,000) 7.414 0.064
HOSUEHOLD ASSETS ($10,000) 41.307 0.597
NUMBER OF CHILDREN AGES 22 AND OLDER 2.764 0.011
NUMBER OF CHILDREN YOUNGER THAN AGE 22 0.201 0.003
SELF-ASSESSED PROBABILITY OF FUTURE NURSING HOME USE 0.085 0.002
PROBABILITY OF FUTURE NURSING HOME USE MISSING 0.506 0.003
NUMBER OF PERSON-YEAR OBSERVATIONS 32,242
NUMBER OF UNIQUE INDIVIDUALS 6,991
SOURCE: Authors' estimates from the HRS. NOTE: The sample consisted of person-year observations between 1992 and 2004 on individuals ages 51-61 in 1992. It excluded people with long-term care insurance coverage in 1992, those who reported any ADL or IADL limitations, kidney problems, history of stroke, or cognitive impairment, and those living in nursing homes. Individuals were dropped from the sample once they purchased coverage.

VI. MODEL ESTIMATES AND POLICY SIMULATIONS

Table VI-1 reports results from our hazard models of time to purchase private long-term care insurance. The first column shows odds ratios for the basic specification. The second column adds the self-assessed probability of future nursing home use to the specification, and the third column adds state identifiers s. The final column decomposes the net expected benefit of coverage into three parts: the expected present discounted value of lifetime premium payments (computed on an after-tax basis), the expected present discounted value of out-of-pocket payments for long-term care services in the absence of private insurance, and the expected present discounted value of out-of-pocket payments in the presence of private insurance.

The overall net expected benefit of coverage significantly increased individual coverage rates, but the effects were modest. In the basic specification, every $1,000 increase in the net expected benefit of coverage would raise purchase probabilities by about 2.4 percent. The estimated impact fell slightly, to 2.3 percent, when we added expected nursing home use and state identifiers to the specification. Under the assumption that premium changes have the same effect on take-up rates as changes in expected out-of-pocket payments for services, this result implies a price elasticity of demand for private long-term care insurance of about -0.75, within the range of estimates in Cramer and Jensen (2006).9 This elasticity is also similar to most estimates of the price elasticity of demand for traditional health insurance, which generally range from -0.1 to -0.9 (Auerbach and Ohri 2006; Marquis and Long 1995; Marquis et al. 2004).10

When we decomposed the expected benefit of coverage into its three components, we did not find a significant effect of the expected lifetime stream of premium payments on long-term care insurance take-up. However, we do not conclude from this evidence that premiums do not influence coverage. Instead, we believe that the lack of variation in premium payments, which fluctuated only by age (which we hold constant in the model) and state of residence, accounts for the insignificant result. The expected stream of out-of-pocket long-term care payments in the absence of private insurance significantly increased insurance take-up, and the expected stream of out-of-pocket payments in the presence of private insurance significantly decreased coverage (with an odds ratio of less than one). It seems implausible that potential policyholders would ignore upfront premiums payments in their take-up decisions while responding to uncertain payments to be made far into the future.

Health, economic, social, and demographic characteristics of older adults significantly influenced the likelihood that people purchased private long-term care insurance. Take-up rates increased with age, and college graduates were much more likely to purchase insurance than those who never attended college. People in excellent or very good health were significantly more likely to obtain coverage than those in worse health, and African Americans and Hispanics were less likely to purchase than other racial groups. Take-up declined with the total number of children, perhaps because children can help with their parents' home care or help finance nursing home costs. Take-up rates increased significantly with the self-reported probability of using nursing home care in the next five years, suggesting that private insurance might be attracting high-cost people. However, policyholders might expect to receive more nursing home care because they have private insurance. Controlling for other factors, we found that take-up rates did not vary significantly with household income or assets.

Policy Simulations

We used the estimated model parameters to simulate the impact of several potential policy reforms on private long-term care insurance coverage. We simulated the effects of changes in the rules for deducting premium expenses from income subject to the federal personal income tax. We considered two broad changes to deduction rules. One set of reforms would allow taxpayers who itemize their deductions to deduct premium expenses regardless of the level of their medical expenses. (Under current law, taxpayers may include premium payments in their medical expenses, but only medical expenses in excess of 7.5 percent of adjusted gross income are tax deductible.) The other set of reforms would allow taxpayers who do not itemize to deduct their premium expenses.

Table VI-2 reports the simulated impact of potential policy reforms on the share of adults ages 63-73 in 2004 who take-up private long-term care insurance between 1992 and 2004. Estimates were based on specification 3 in Table VI-1. The results indicated that liberalizing rules for deducting premium expenses from taxable income could modestly increase take-up rates. For example, the model showed that granting a full tax deduction to all itemizers, even those who spend less than 7.5 percent of adjusted gross income on medical expenses, would boost take-up rates by about 3 percentage points, from 14 percent to 17 percent, increasing the number of adults with coverage by about 21 percent.11 The effects would be larger if the law changed to allow taxpayers to deduct their long-term care insurance premium expenses even if they did not itemize their deductions. Take-up rates would rise to 19 percent if all taxpayers could fully deduct premium expenses from income subject to federal income taxes, representing about a 36 percent boost in the number of older adults with coverage. Allowing taxpayers to deduct only 25 percent of the premium cost would do very little to boost coverage. However, granting policyholders a 25 percent tax credit to offset premium expenses would raise overall take-up rates to 20 percent.

Tax incentives would boost long-term care insurance take-up rates for high-income taxpayers, but would have little impact for lower-income groups. For example, allowing all policyholders to deduct their entire premium costs from taxable income would raise take-up rates from 20 percent to 32 percent for people in the top income quartile and from 16 percent to 21 percent for people in the third income quartile. However, rates would increase by only 1 percentage point (from 6 percent to 7 percent) for those in the bottom income quartile and by 2 percentage points for those in the second quartile. Whites and well-educated people would also gain more from these tax incentives, because they tend to have higher incomes than African Americans, Hispanics, and people with limited education.

Tax incentives that increase private insurance coverage would have little impact on Medicaid costs. Few new policyholders would have otherwise qualified for Medicaid, because most people with long-term care insurance are relatively affluent. Table VI-3 shows the share of our sample that we project will someday receive Medicaid-financed nursing home care. Policy reforms allowing all policyholders to deduct all of their long-term care insurance premium payments from taxable income would have negligible effects on Medicaid costs, reducing the share of our sample that eventually use Medicaid-financed nursing home care from 18.4 percent to 18.2 percent. Our projections indicate that only 3 percent of those who would take-up coverage under this policy reform but not under current law would eventually qualify for Medicaid.

TABLE VI-1. Estimated Odds Ratios of the Purchase of Private Long-Term Care Insurance, with Standard Errors in Parentheses
  (1) (2) (3) (4)
NET EXPECTED BENEFIT OF COVERAGE ($1,000)   1.024***  (0.004)   1.024***  (0.004)   1.023***  (0.005) ---
PDV OF LIFETIME PREMIUM PAYMENTS ($1,000) --- --- ---   1.009  (0.007)
PDV OF OUT-OF-POCKET PAYMENTS WITHOUT PRIVATE INSURANCE ($1,000) --- --- --- 1.054***(0.010)
PDV OF OUT-OF-POCKET PAYMENTS WITH PRIVATE INSURANCE ($1,000) --- --- --- 0.948***(0.010)
AGE 1.072***(0.016) 1.082***(0.023) 1.078***(0.023) 1.012(0.024)
HEALTH STATUS
   [Reference: Excellent or very good] --- --- --- ---
   Good 0.802**(0.080) 0.795**(0.079) 0.795**(0.080) 0.807**(0.080)
   Fair or poor 0.571***(0.101) 0.559***(0.098) 0.574***(0.102) 0.581***(0.102)
EDUCATION
   Not high school graduate 0.705**(0.115) 0.711**(0.116) 0.737*(0.122) 0.745*(0.121)
   [Reference: High school graduate] --- --- --- ---
   Some college 0.819(0.105) 0.827(0.106) 0.825(0.109) 0.815(0.104)
   College graduate 2.002***(0.218) 2.006***(0.218) 2.052***(0.232) 1.989***(0.214)
MARRIED 1.130(0.131) 1.127(0.131) 1.132(0.135) 1.063(0.121)
FEMALE 0.798(0.114) 0.798(0.114) 0.843(0.127) 0.375***(0.100)
RACE
   African American 0.445***(0.092) 0.442***(0.091) 0.471***(0.100) 0.482***(0.099)
   Hispanic 0.414**(0.152) 0.416**(0.153) 0.404**(0.153) 0.431**(0.159)
   [Reference: White or other] --- --- --- ---
HOUSEHOLD INCOME ($10,000) 1.007(0.004) 1.007(0.004) 1.006(0.005) 1.006(0.004)
HOUSEHOLD ASSETS ($10,000) 1.000(0.0003) 1.000(0.0003) 1.000(0.0003) 1.000(0.0003)
NUMBER OF CHILDREN YOUNGER THAN AGE 22 0.726**(0.094) 0.733**(0.094) 0.705***(0.094) 0.725**(0.095)
NUMBER OF CHILDREN AGES 22 AND OLDER 0.924***(0.024) 0.924***(0.024) 0.905***(0.024) 0.925***(0.024)
SELF-ASSESSED PROBABILITY OF FUTURE NURSING HOME USE --- 3.269***(0.918) 3.098***(0.887) 3.355***(0.946)
INDICATOR FOR MISSING NURSING HOME PROBABILITY --- 1.312*(0.190) 1.327*(0.194) 1.325*(0.194)
INTERVIEW YEAR
   [Reference: 1992] --- --- --- ---
   1994 1.934***(0.419) 1.547*(0.393) 1.558*(0.396) 1.590*(0.411)
   1996 3.217***(0.668) 2.184***(0.541) 2.243***(0.554) 2.309***(0.583)
   1998 5.416***(1.119) 4.094***(1.126) 4.174***(1.148) 4.418***(1.248)
   2000 3.371***(0.754) 2.529***(0.740) 2.619***(0.765) 2.695***(0.810)
   2002 4.586***(1.075) 3.430***(1.079) 3.602***(1.127) 3.533***(1.145)
STATE INDICATORS No No Yes No
F Statistic 22.91 21.86 9.75 18.65
SOURCE: Authors' estimates from the HRS. NOTE: Results were generated from logit models estimated on a sample of 32,242 person-year observations between 1992 and 2004 on 6,991 individuals ages 51-61 in 1992. The sample excluded people with long-term care insurance coverage in 1992, those who reported any ADL or IADL limitations, kidney problems, history of stroke, or cognitive impairment, and those living in nursing homes. Individuals were dropped from the sample once they purchased coverage. PDV = present discounted value. * significant at 10 percent level. ** significant at the 5 percent level. *** significant at the 1 percent level.
TABLE VI-2. Share of Adults Ages 63-73 in 2004 Who Took Up Private Long-Term Care Insurance Coverage Between 1992 and 2004, Under Current Law and Alternative Policy Scenarios (%)
    Current Law     Tax Credit   Tax Deductions
Itemizers Only All Filers
25%   25%     65%     100%     25%     65%     100%  
ALL 14 20 14 16 17 15 17 19
GENDER
   Male 13 21 14 16 17 15 17 19
   Female 15 21 15 16 17 16 18 19
RACE
   African American 5 8 6 6 6 6 7 8
   Hispanic 4 6 4 4 4 4 5 5
   White, Other 15 23 16 17 18 16 19 21
EDUCATION
   Less than High School 7 11 7 7 7 7 9 10
   High School Graduate 12 20 12 13 13 13 15 17
   Some College 11 19 12 13 14 12 14 16
   College Graduate 25 36 26 29 31 27 30 35
INCOME QUARTILE
   First 6 10 6 6 6 7 7 7
   Second 12 16 12 12 12 12 13 14
   Third 16 23 17 17 17 17 19 21
   Fourth 20 30 22 25 28 23 27 32
SOURCE: Authors' estimates from the HRS. NOTE: Results were based on a discrete-time hazard model, described in column 3 of Table VI-1. Estimates excluded people with long-term care insurance coverage in 1992, those who reported any ADL or IADL limitations, kidney problems, history of stroke, or cognitive impairment, and those living in nursing homes.
TABLE VI-3. Impact of Long-Term Care Insurance Policy Reforms on Medicaid-Financed Nursing Home Care
  Percent of SampleProjected to Receive  Future Medicaid-Financed  Nursing Home Care
Entire Sample, Under Current Law 18.4
Entire Sample, Assuming All Policyholders Could Deduct 100% of Premiums from Taxable Income 18.2
People Who Would Purchase Coverage if All Policyholders Could Deduct 100% of Premiums from Taxable Income, But Would Not Purchase Coverage Under Current Law 3.0
SOURCE: Authors' estimates from the HRS. NOTE: Estimates excluded people with long-term care insurance coverage in 1992, those who reported any ADL or IADL limitations, kidney problems, history of stroke, or cognitive impairment, and those living in nursing homes.

VII. CONCLUSIONS

Our results show that the decision to purchase private long-term care insurance responds to the expected benefit of coverage. People become significantly more likely to take-up coverage as the net expected benefit increases, say because premiums fall, the likelihood of using services rises, the cost of services without insurance rises, or the chances of qualifying for Medicaid falls. However, the effects are modest. Under the assumption that premium changes have the same effect on take-up rates as changes in expected out-of-pocket payments for services, our findings imply a price elasticity of demand for private long-term care insurance of about -0.75, consistent with the estimates in Cramer and Jensen (2006), which ranged from -0.23 to -0.87. This elasticity is also similar to most estimates of the price elasticity of demand for traditional health insurance, which generally range from -0.1 to -0.9 (Auerbach and Ohri 2006; Marquis and Long 1995; Marquis et al. 2004).

Our estimates suggest that liberalizing rules for deducting long-term care insurance premiums from taxable income could modestly increase take-up rates. For example, the number of older adults who take-up coverage would increase by about 21 percent if all taxpayers who itemize their deductions, including those who spend less than 7.5 percent of adjusted gross income on medical expenses, could deduct the full premium cost of long-term care insurance from their taxable income. Granting a full tax deduction to all policyholders, even those who do not itemize their deductions, would boost the number of older adults who take-up coverage by about 36 percent. Nearly one in five older adults would purchase long-term care insurance if they could deduct the full premium expenses from their taxable income. These tax incentives would spur coverage among high-income taxpayers, but they would have very little impact on coverage rates for adults in the bottom half of the income distribution.

REFERENCES

AARP. 2001. The Costs of Long-Term Care: Public Perceptions Versus Reality. Washington, DC: AARP.

_____. Various years. Across the States: Profiles of Long-Term Care. Washington, DC: AARP.

Allison, Paul D. 1994. Event History Analysis. Beverly Hills, CA: Sage.

American Council of Life Insurers (ACLI). 2003. "ACLI Product Line Report: Long-Term Care." Washington, DC: ACLI.

America's Health Insurance Plans (AHIP). 2004. "Long-Term Care Insurance in 2002." Washington, DC: AHIP.

Auerbach, David, and Sabina Ohri. 2006. "Price and the Demand for Nongroup Health Insurance." Inquiry 43(2):122-134.

Brown, Jeffrey R., and Amy Finkelstein. 2004a. "The Interaction of Public and Private Insurance: Medicaid and the Long-Term Care Insurance Market." NBER Working Paper 10989. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.

_____. 2004b. "Supply or Demand: Why is the Market for Long-Term Care Insurance So Small?" NBER Working Paper 10782. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.

Bruen, Brian K., Joshua M. Wiener, and Seema Thomas. 2003. "Medicaid Eligibility Policy for Aged, Blind, and Disabled Beneficiaries." AARP Public Policy Institute Report No. 2003-14. Washington, DC: AARP.

Center for Medicare Education. 2004. "Understanding Long-Term Care Insurance." Issue Brief Vol. 5, No. 5. Washington, DC: Center for Medicare Education.

Cohen, Marc A., Maurice Weinrobe, and Jessica Miller. 2002. "Inflation Protection and Long-Term Care Insurance: Finding the Gold Standard of Adequacy." AARP Public Policy Institute Report No. 2002-09. Washington, DC: AARP.

Congressional Budget Office. 2004. Financing Long-Term Care for the Elderly. Washington, DC: Congressional Budget Office.

Cramer, Anne Theisen, and Gail A. Jensen. 2006. "Why Don't People Buy Long-Term Care Insurance?" Journal of Gerontology: Social Sciences 61B:S185-S193.

Dick, Andrew, Alan M. Garber, and Thomas A. MaCurdy. 1994. "Forecasting Nursing Home Utilization of Elderly Americans." In Studies in the Economics of Aging, edited by David A. Wise (365-394). Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.

Finkelstein, Amy, and Kathleen McGarry. 2006. "Multiple Dimensions of Private Information: Evidence from the Long-Term Care Insurance Market." American Economic Review 96(4):938-958.

Finkelstein, Amy, Kathleen McGarry, and Amir Sufi. 2005. "Dynamic Inefficiencies in Insurance Markets: Evidence from Long-Term Care Insurance." NBER Working Paper 11039. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.

Gruber, Jonathan, and James Poterba. 1994. "Tax Incentives and the Decision to Purchase Health Insurance: Evidence from the Self-Employed." Quarterly Journal of Economics 109(3):701-33.

Heffler, Stephen, Sheila Smith, Sean Keehan, Christine Borger, M. Kent Clemens, and Christopher Truffer. 2005. "U.S. Health Spending Projections for 2004-2014." Health Affairs Web Exclusive W5:74-85.

Internal Revenue Service. 2006. "2002, Individual Income Tax Returns with Itemized Deductions, by Size of Adjusted Gross Income." http://www.irs.gov/pub/irs-soi/02in03ga.xls.

Johnson, Richard W., Marilyn Moon, and Amy J. Davidoff. 2002. A Medicare Buy-In for the Near-Elderly: Design Issues and Potential Effects on Coverage. Washington, DC: Kaiser Family Foundation.

Johnson, Richard W., Gordon B.T. Mermin, and Cori E. Uccello. 2005. "When the Nest Egg Cracks: Financial Consequences of Health Problems, Marital Status Changes, and Job Layoffs at Older Ages." CRR Working Paper No. 2005-18. Chestnut Hill, MA: Center for Retirement Research at Boston College.

Kemper, Peter, Harriet L. Komisar, and Lisa Alecxih. 2005/2006. "Long-Term Care Over an Uncertain Future: What Can Current Retirees Expect?" Inquiry 42(4):335-350.

Kemper, Peter, and Christopher M. Murtaugh. 1991. "Lifetime Use of Nursing Home Care." New England Journal of Medicine 324:595-600.

Kumar, Nanda, Marc A. Cohen, Christine E. Bishop, and Stanley S. Wallack. 1995. "Understanding the Factors behind the Decision to Purchase Varying Coverage Amounts of Long-Term Care Insurance." Health Services Research 29(6):653-678.

LifePlans, Inc. 2000. "Who Buys Long-Term Care Insurance in 2000? A Decade of Study of Buyers and Nonbuyers." Washington, DC: Health Insurance Association of America.

LIMRA International and the Society of Actuaries. 2004. "Long-Term Care Insurance Persistency Experience." Windsor, CT: LIMRA International.

Marquis, M. Susan, and Stephen H. Long. 1995. "Worker Demand for Health Insurance in the Non-Group Market." Journal of Health Economics 14:47-63.

Marquis, M. Susan, Melinda Beeuwkes Buntin, Jose J. Escarce, Kanika Kapur, and Jill M. Yegian. 2004. "Subsidies and the Demand for Individual Health Insurance in California." Health Services Research 39(5):1547-1570.

McNamara, Paul E., and Nayoung Lee. 2004. "Long-term Care Insurance Policy Dropping in the U.S. from 1996 to 2000: Evidence and Implications for Long-term Care Financing." The Geneva Papers on Risk and Insurance 29(4):640-651.

Mellor, Jennifer M. 2001. "Long-Term Care and Nursing Home Coverage: Are Adult Children Substitutes for Insurance Policies?" Journal of Health Economics 20:527-547.

MetLife. Various years. "The MetLife Market Survey of Nursing Home and Home Care Costs." Westport, CT: MetLife Mature Market Institute.

Murtaugh, Christopher M., Peter Kemper, and Brenda C. Spillman. 1995. "Lifetime Patterns of Payment for Nursing Home Care." Medical Care 33(3):280-296.

Murtaugh, Christopher M., Peter Kemper, Brenda C. Spillman, and Barbara L. Carlson. 1997. "Amount, Distribution, and Timing of Lifetime Nursing Home Use." Medical Care 35(3):204-218.

Spillman, Brenda C., and James Lubitz. 2002. "New Estimates of Lifetime Nursing Home Use: Have Patterns of Use Changed?" Medical Care 40(10):969-975.

U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics. 2006. "National Compensation Survey: Employee Benefits in Private Industry in the United States, March 2006." Available at http://www.bls.gov/ncs/ebs/sp/ebsm0004.pdf.

Uccello, Cori E. 2001. "Are Americans Saving Enough for Retirement?" Issue in Brief No. 7. Chestnut Hill, MA: Center for Retirement Research at Boston College.

Weiss Ratings, Inc. 2002. "Weiss Ratings' Consumer Guide to LTC Insurance." Palm Beach Gardens, FL: Weiss Ratings, Inc.

Wiener, Joshua, Laurel Hixon Illston, and Raymond Hanley. 1994. Sharing the Burden: Strategies for Public and Private Long-Term Care Insurance. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press.

Wiener, Joshua M., Catherine M. Sullivan, and Jason Skaggs. 1996. "Spending Down to Medicaid: New Data on the Role of Medicaid in Paying for Nursing Home Care." AARP Public Policy Institute Report No. 9607. Washington, DC: American Association of Retired Persons.

NOTES

  1. LIMRA and SOA acknowledge that their reported lapse rates could be overstated if some unreported deaths were counted as voluntary lapses.

  2. Finkelstein, McGarry, and Sufi (2005) conclude that many people who let their policies lapse choose to drop their coverage because they realize that their risk of needing long-term care services is lower than they originally thought.

  3. Some of these findings appear to be at odds with the results from the LifePlans, Inc. (2000). For example, Kumar et al. (1995) found that those with limited schooling were more likely to purchase insurance than college graduates, whereas the LifePlans study showed that college graduates were more likely to purchase. Similarly, Kumar and colleagues did not find a significant effect of asset holdings on the purchase decision, whereas LifePlans found that coverage rates increased with wealth. The differences probably arise from the fact that Kumar and colleagues control for other factors in their model, whereas LifePlans reports simple cross-tabulations. Thus, college graduates may have higher coverage rates than nongraduates, but their rates may be lower holding financial resources constant.

  4. The only price variation in their study comes from the age of the policyholder and discounts for nonsmokers, presumably making it nearly impossible to estimate the model while controlling for the policyholder’s age.

  5. This approach is a simplified version of the method developed by Brown and Finkelstein (2004a) to show why prototypical adults are unlikely to purchase private long-term care insurance. Using dynamic programming techniques, they traced out the optimal consumption path for typical 65-year-old men and women and demonstrated that only the wealthiest individuals could gain from the purchase of private insurance. The simplified version that we describe is more tractable than the Brown and Finkelstein specification.

  6. The 1948-1953 cohorts were added in 2004, and the 1954-1959 will be added in 2010.

  7. The 2000 HRS sample includes all respondents who reported purchasing long-term care insurance, even those whose policies may in fact be traditional health insurance plans. This misclassification probably has only a small impact on the profile of new long-term care insurance purchasers, however, because there are only minor differences in the 2002 HRS buyer profiles between the sample that includes everyone who reported long-term care coverage and the subset of those with policies that differed from their traditional health insurance plans.

  8. Weiss collected premium data from Bankers Life and Casualty, Blue Cross Blue Shield of Minnesota, Catholic Order of Foresters, Cincinnati Life Insurance, Colonial American Life Insurance, Combined Insurance Company of America, Country Life Insurance, Equitable Life and Casualty, Farmers New World Life Insurance, First Unum Life Insurance, General Electric Capital Assurance, Great Republic Life Insurance, Guaranty Income Life Insurance, John Hancock, Kanawha, Mutual of Omaha, New York Life, Penn Treaty Network America, Physicians Mutual, Provident Life and Accident, State Farm, Teachers Protective Mutual Life, TIAA-CREF Life Insurance, United American, United Security Assurance Co. of Pennsylvania, and Unum Life.

  9. The estimated odds ratio for the net expected benefit of coverage in specification 3 implies that every additional $1,000 lifetime premium payment would reduce take-up rates by 0.05 percentage points (0.023 times the average take-up rate in the sample of 0.022). Thus, a 10 percent increase in lifetime premium payments, roughly equivalent to an additional $3,300 in payments, would reduce take-up rates by about 0.165 percentage points.

  10. Gruber and Poterba (1994), however, found that traditional health insurance coverage was more price sensitive for self-employed workers, for whom they estimated a price elasticity of demand of -1.8.

  11. These estimates assumed that people did not let their policies lapse.


To obtain a printed copy of this report, send the full report title and your mailing information to:

U.S. Department of Health and Human ServicesOffice of Disability, Aging and Long-Term Care PolicyRoom 424E, H.H. Humphrey Building200 Independence Avenue, S.W.Washington, D.C. 20201FAX:  202-401-7733Email:  webmaster.DALTCP@hhs.gov


RETURN TO:

Office of Disability, Aging and Long-Term Care Policy (DALTCP) Home [http://aspe.hhs.gov/_/office_specific/daltcp.cfm]Assistant Secretary for Planning and Evaluation (ASPE) Home [http://aspe.hhs.gov]U.S. Department of Health and Human Services Home [http://www.hhs.gov]