This report looks at the changing nature of the caseload by examining the characteristics and circumstances of three groups: people who leave welfare and stay off for at least a year (leavers), people who stay on welfare persistently (stayers), and people who cycle on and off the rolls (cyclers). The report uses a unique data set consisting of over 30,000 people who were targeted for a variety of welfare-to-work programs over the past decade. The programs were each evaluated using a random assignment design and included three components — mandatory participation in employment or education activities, enhanced financial incentives, and time limits — used alone and in combination."
Acknowledgments
This report benefited from the input of many people. At ASPE, Susan Hauan provided suggestions on the analysis plan and an earlier draft of the report. At MDRC, Barbara Goldman and Charles Michalopoulos provided helpful comments on an earlier draft. Vanessa Martin provided programming assistance and help with report production.
Summary
Between 1994 and 1999, the welfare caseload fell by almost 50 percent. In other words, about two million fewer families were receiving welfare in 1999 than five years earlier. To some observers, this trend is evidence that welfare reform has been a success. To others, it raises a host of new questions and concerns and suggests that the 1996 law was only the first step in the process of reforming welfare. For example, how are the families who have left welfare doing? Are most of them working and earning enough to lift themselves above poverty? And who are the families who are still left on the welfare rolls? Do they face especially severe circumstances that may prevent them from going to work?
This report looks at the changing nature of the caseload by examining the characteristics and circumstances of three groups: people who leave welfare and stay off for at least a year (leavers), people who stay on welfare persistently (stayers), and people who cycle on and off the rolls (cyclers). The report uses a unique data set consisting of over 30,000 people who were targeted for a variety of welfare-to-work programs over the past decade. The programs were each evaluated using a random assignment design, in which some families were assigned into the new program being tested and others were assigned into the existing welfare system in the state at the time of the evaluation. The programs include three key components—mandatory participation in employment or education activities, enhanced financial incentives, and time limits—used alone and in combination. Together, they cover the range of policies that states now have adopted as part of their new welfare programs. Data from these welfare-to-work programs make it possible to track the employment, welfare, and economic status of families for up to five years after they entered the evaluation. By dividing the caseload into stayers, leavers, and cyclers, the following key questions can be addressed:
- Who is leaving welfare long term? What potential employment barriers do welfare leavers face, and how are they faring economically? How do their circumstances differ from those of people who stay on welfare persistently and of people who cycle on and off welfare?
-
How many families leave welfare without work? Who are they, and what potential employment barriers do they face? How are they faring relative to families who are working when they leave welfare?
-
What effects have welfare-to-work programs had on the caseload? Who remains on welfare persistently, despite being subject to a welfare-to-work program? Do they face more barriers to employment than people who stay under the traditional AFDC system?
Understanding the circumstances of families who leave welfare long term is important to designing effective programs for welfare recipients and for low-income families in general. If many who do work are still poor, for example, more effort might be devoted to post-employment services that help low-wage workers increase their earnings.It is equally important to find out about the families who stay on welfare. If many of the families receiving welfare today face severe employment barriers, then welfare policies that have been used in the past may not work for this new type of caseload. Finding new policies for the hard-to-employ may have also gained added urgency if welfare reform, by encouraging more and more families to leave welfare, has left a caseload that is even harder to employ than in the past. Examining the effects of several welfare-to-work programs on the composition of the caseload provides hints as to the effects of welfare reform more broadly. Finally, there has been little research on cyclers, or people who return to welfare intermittently but do not stay on it persistently. It is not clear, for example, whether cyclers face more dire economic circumstances than stayers and leavers or whether they possess fewer or more barriers to employment.
Findings
- Long-term welfare leavers face fewer barriers to employment than long-term stayers and generally fare better economically. People who cycle on and off the welfare rolls look more similar to leavers than to stayers.
Leavers differed from stayers in a variety of expected ways (see Table S1). Leavers were older, more educated, and had fewer children than stayers. They also faced fewer barriers to employment; they were less likely to report child care problems, for example, and were more likely to have had work experience prior to entering the evaluation. Cyclers, on the other hand, looked fairly similar to long-term leavers, in part because many of them had only one or two short spells on welfare.
Although each of the groups had low incomes during the follow-up period, leavers and cyclers had somewhat higher incomes than stayers and were much less likely to have income below the poverty line. However, leavers and cyclers were more likely to report facing material hardships, particularly problems in accessing health care.
- More than one-third of welfare leavers did not work in the months immediately following their welfare exit. These nonworking leavers faced more barriers to work than other leavers but had similar incomes.
Thirty-six percent of long-term welfare leavers did not work in the months immediately following their exit, according to earnings data from state Unemployment Insurance systems. In general, people who did not work at welfare exit were more disadvantaged than those who did work (see Table S2). They were less educated, more likely to report other barriers to work, and much less likely to have had recent work experience. On average, however, they had similar incomes as working leavers by the time of the follow-up survey. Although they had lower earnings, they were more likely to rely on other sources of income and more likely to eventually return to welfare, Food Stamps, or both. There is little evidence that many nonworking leavers left welfare for marriage or cohabitation.
Table S1: Characteristics of Stayers, Leavers, and Cyclers
Table S2: Characteristics of Nonworking and Working Leavers
- People who stayed on welfare while subject to a welfare-to-work program had similar characteristics and employment barriers as people who stayed on welfare under the traditional AFDC system.
The effects of welfare reform on the characteristics of the caseload can be inferred by comparing stayers in the program groups with their counterparts in the control groups. People in the program groups were subject to one of the programs being tested—each of which contains elements of states’ new Temporary Assistance for Needy Families (TANF) pro-grams—while those in the control group were subject to the traditional AFDC system. In general, the two groups looked fairly similar in terms of demographic characteristics and potential barriers to employment (see Table S3).
Table S3: Characteristics of Stayers in the Program Versus Control Groups
- People who stayed on welfare while subject to a welfare-to-work program had more work experience during the follow-up period than people who stayed under the traditional AFDC system. These differences were found only for the two welfare-to-work programs with the most generous financial incentives.
Although several programs included financial incentives to work, in the form of enhanced earnings disregards, stayers in the two programs with the most generous incentives differed in two key ways from their control group counterparts. First, stayers in the program groups were more likely to have worked while on welfare, because the earnings disregards allowed more of them to work and still qualify for benefits. Second, because stayers in the program groups were more likely to have worked and because they received more generous welfare benefits when they did work, they had higher incomes than stayers in the control groups.
*****
The findings show that many families continue to need assistance after they leave welfare. Many families who leave and stay off long term remain poor after they leave, and many lack access to important benefits, such as Food Stamps and health insurance, for which they are probably still eligible. People who leave welfare without work have always been a group of special concern, and the findings indicate that they did not leave welfare without work because they got married. Rather, they were unable to overcome a range of potential barriers to work, such as low education and little prior work experience. These leavers need services to help them find and keep jobs. It is encouraging that people who cycle on and off welfare do not face more severe employment barriers than other groups in the caseload. Nonetheless, many of them obviously need assistance to avoid returning to welfare, which may not be an option in the era of time limits. Finally, although welfare-to-work programs were found to have few effects on the characteristics of the caseload, they do affect stayers’ economic status. Enhanced incentives, in particular, increase both the employment rates and the incomes of stayers. Although the fact that most states now use enhanced incentives is encouraging, most states also impose time limits. Time-limit policies could be designed so that the “leavers” who are forced off the welfare rolls by these programs would have adequate incomes. Time limits could also be combined with post-exit services that would be available to all leavers.
Introduction
Between 1994 and 1999, the welfare caseload fell by almost 50 percent. In other words, about two million fewer families were receiving welfare in 1999 than five years earlier. To some observers, this trend is evidence that welfare reform has been a success. To others, it raises a host of new questions and concerns and suggests that the 1996 law was only the first step in the process of reforming welfare.
One of the primary concerns has been about families who have left welfare. Who are these families, and how are they faring? Are most of them working? If so, are they working at jobs that pay enough to lift them out of poverty, or have many of them fallen further into poverty since leaving welfare?
The dramatic fall in the number of families receiving welfare has also raised concerns about the changing nature of the caseload. One key question is whether the welfare caseload has come to comprise primarily the hardest-to-employ recipients. Who are the families who are still on welfare? Why have they not left welfare when so many other families have? Do they face especially severe circumstances that may prevent them from going to work?
A fair amount of research has been conducted over the past several years to address these questions, although most of it focuses only on people who have left welfare (Office of the Assistant Secretary for Planning and Evaluation, 2001; Brauner and Loprest, 1999). In general, the research shows that most leavers are working. There is little evidence that many leavers have fallen further into poverty, but most are still poor. Much of the research on leavers focuses on people who “ever left” welfare at some point in the recent past, which includes a fair number who may have returned to welfare fairly quickly. In contrast, the research on the caseload finds that people who are still on welfare do, on average, face more barriers to employment than those who have left. In this case, the caseload, or “stayers,” is defined as all people who were receiving welfare at a point in time, regardless of whether they recently started receiving benefits or will receive benefits for only a few months.
This report looks at the changing nature of the caseload from a slightly different perspective, by examining the characteristics and circumstances of three groups: people who leave welfare and stay off for at least a year (leavers), people who stay on welfare persistently (stayers), and people who intermittently cycle on and off the rolls (cyclers). Many of the “leavers” in other studies returned to welfare fairly quickly. Would the conclusions about who leavers are and how they fare differ if the focus were on a group that left welfare and stayed off? Similarly, persistent stayers may be a more policy-relevant group than the entire caseload at a point in time, since they are the ones who will be left on the rolls in the long run. There has also been little research on the people who cycle on and off welfare.
This report uses a unique data set consisting of over 30,000 people who were targeted for a variety of welfare-to-work programs over the past decade. The programs were each evaluated using a random assignment design, in which some families were assigned into the new program being tested and others were assigned into the existing welfare system in the state at the time of the evaluation. The programs include three key components—mandatory participation in employment or education activities, enhanced financial incentives, and time limits—used alone and in combination. Together, they cover the range of policies that states now have adopted as part of their new welfare programs. By using data from these welfare-to-work programs and dividing the caseload into stayers, leavers, and cyclers, the following key questions can be addressed:
Leavers, stayers, and cyclers
Nonworking leavers
The effects of welfare-to-work programs on the caseload
- Who are the people who stay on welfare persistently, despite being subject to a welfare-to-work program? Compared with people who stayed on welfare under the old system, are they more disadvantaged, and do they face more barriers to employment?
Understanding the circumstances of families who leave welfare long term is important to designing effective programs for welfare recipients and for low-income families in general. If many who do work are still poor, for example, more effort might be devoted to post-employment services that help low-wage workers increase their earnings. It is equally important to find out about the families who stay on welfare. If many of the families receiving welfare today face severe employment barriers, then welfare policies that have been used in the past may not work for this new type of caseload. Finding new policies for the hard-to-employ may have also gained added urgency if welfare reform, by encouraging more and more families to leave welfare, has left a caseload that is even harder to employ than in the past. By examining the effects of several welfare-to-work programs on the composition of the caseload, we can glimpse the effects of welfare more broadly. Finally, there has been little research on cyclers, or people who return to welfare intermittently but do not stay on it persistently. It is not clear, for example, whether cyclers face more dire economic circumstances than stayers and leavers or whether they possess fewer or more barriers to employment.
Findings in Brief
Leavers, Stayers, and Cyclers
- Leavers differed from stayers in a variety of expected ways: They were older, more educated, and had fewer children than stayers. They also faced fewer barriers to employment; they were less likely to report child care problems and were more likely to have had recent work experience.
-
Cyclers looked very similar to leavers in terms of demographic characteristics and, on average, faced fewer potential barriers to employment. Part of the reason for this finding is that many of the people who are defined as cyclers had only one or two very short spells of welfare during the observation period.
-
Although each of the groups had low incomes, leavers and cyclers had somewhat higher incomes than stayers and were much less likely to have income below the poverty line. However, leavers and cyclers were more likely to report facing material hardships, particularly problems in accessing health care.
-
The results were consistent across each of the welfare-to-work programs. The time-limit programs, however, had two types of leavers: people who left welfarebeforereaching their time limit and people who left welfare because of reaching their time limit. In one program, time-limit leavers were relatively more disadvantaged and had lower incomes than other leavers. This pattern did not occur in the other time-limit program, because extensions were granted to families who had reached their time limit and did not have sufficient earnings. Thus, the way in which the time limit is administered affects who leaves welfare and how they fare.
Nonworking Leavers
- About one-third of welfare leavers in these programs did not work in the months immediately following their welfare exit. Compared with people who did work, nonworkers had lower education levels, reported more barriers to employment, and were much less likely to have had recent work experience.
-
At the time of the follow-up surveys, nonworking leavers had similar incomes as working leavers. Although fewer nonworkers reported income from earnings, more of them had income from other sources, and more had returned to welfare and Food Stamps. There is little evidence that many nonworking leavers left welfare for marriage or cohabitation.
-
The results were consistent across each of the welfare-to-work programs. In the programs with the most generous financial incentives, however, there were significant income differences between nonworkers and workers, largely because of the relatively high incomes of the working leavers. The reason for this difference is the generous earned income disregards, under which recipients could earn higher amounts before becoming ineligible for benefits.
The Effects of Welfare-to-Work Programs on the Caseload
- With respect to demographic characteristics, stayers in each of the welfare-to-work programs (or the program group) looked fairly similar to stayers under the traditional AFDC system (or the control group). Stayers in the program groups faced fewer potential employment barriers than stayers in the control groups, although these differences were fairly small.
-
In the programs with the most generous financial incentives, the program and control groups differed in two ways. First, stayers in the program groups were more likely to have worked while on welfare, because the earnings disregards allowed more of them to work and still qualify for benefits. Second, because stayers in the program groups were more likely to have worked and because they received more generous welfare benefits when they did work, they had higher incomes than stayers in the control groups.
*****
One implication of these results is that many families continue to need assistance after they leave welfare, and this applies to all types of leavers. Many families who leave and stay off welfare long term, for example, are still poor after they leave, and many lack access to important benefits for which they are probably still eligible, such as Food Stamps and health insurance. People who leave welfare without work are probably without jobs because of a range of potential barriers to work, such as low education and little prior work experience, and not because they left welfare for marriage. These leavers need services to help them find and keep jobs. It is encouraging that cyclers - at least as defined here - do not face more severe employment barriers than other groups in the caseload. Nonetheless, many obviously need assistance to avoid returning to welfare, especially since they will not have the option of doing so if they are subject to time limits. Thus, for policymakers and low-income families alike, welfare reform was just the first step in a longer process.
Finally, although welfare-to-work programs have been found to have few effects on the characteristics of the caseload, they do affect stayers’ economic status. Enhanced incentives, in particular, increase both the employment rates and the incomes of stayers. Although most states now use enhanced incentives, most states also impose time limits. Time-limit policies could be designed so that the “leavers” who are forced off the welfare rolls by these programs would have adequate incomes. Time limits could also be combined with post-exit services that would be available to all leavers.
The next section reviews the existing research in this area and is followed by a discussion of the data and methods used for the analysis. The subsequent three sections present the results, beginning with a comparison of leavers, stayers, and cyclers; then examining results for nonworking leavers; and finally presenting the effects of the welfare-to-work programs on the characteristics of the caseload, or stayers. Each of these sections presents results first for the combined sample and then for each welfare-to-work program separately. The report concludes with a summary and some suggestions for ensuring that people will, in fact, be better off when they leave welfare.
Background
One of the first steps in understanding how leavers are faring and how the caseload has changed is figuring out why the caseload declined so dramatically since the early 1990s. Did most families leave because they found jobs in the expanding economy, or did they leave because of welfare reform? Caseload declines that are driven by the economy should result in fewer negative effects on family income or well being, since many families presumably left as they got jobs or increased their earnings and became ineligible for benefits. In this case, those who leave welfare will probably be the most employable segment of the caseload. Caseload declines that are driven by welfare policies, on the other hand, may encourage both more and less employable recipients to leave welfare and, by doing so, may make some families worse off, if they were encouraged to leave before making a solid transition to work. In addition, different welfare policies may have different effects. Time limits have generated the most concern in terms of their potential for negatively affecting families. There is some debate about what factor played the major role in the caseload decline, but all generally agree that both the expanding economy and welfare reform had important effects (Wallace and Blank, 1999; Council of Economic Advisors, 1999).
Leavers
The most direct way to assess how the caseload decline has affected families is to track the economic status of welfare leavers. This task has been the focus of a substantial amount of research over the past several years (Office of the Assistant Secretary for Planning and Evaluation, 2001; Cancian, Haveman, Meyer, and Wolfe, 2000; Brauner and Loprest, 1999). In 1998, for example, the U.S. Department of Health and Human Services (HHS) funded a series of “leaver” studies in 11 states and three counties. The studies follow recipients who left welfare for at least two consecutive months during a given period, tracking their post-exit outcomes, such as employment, earnings, welfare recidivism, and family income (Office of the Assistant Secretary for Planning and Evaluation, 2001). Employment, earnings, and benefit receipt are typically tracked using state administrative records data, while data on family income and well-being are obtained from follow-up surveys, administered anywhere from six months to three years after the welfare exit. Another source of information on leavers is the National Survey of America’s Families (NSAF) conducted by the Urban Institute (Brauner and Loprest, 1999). The NSAF was administered in 1997 and again in 1999 to a nationally representative sample of the civilian population under age 65.
Both the HHS-sponsored studies and those using the NSAF data have provided evidence on who leaves welfare and how they fare. Leavers are typically defined in this research as people who left welfare at some point in the two years prior to the survey and were not receiving welfare at the time of the survey. The findings from all the studies are fairly consistent in that leavers look less disadvantaged and more employable than stayers. Leavers are more educated; they have fewer children; they are less likely to have young children; and they are more likely to have prior work experience (Verma and Colton, 2001; Acs, Loprest, and Roberts, 2001; Loprest and Zedlewski, 1999).
In terms of how families fare after leaving welfare, the research focuses on three types of outcomes: work, welfare, and income (Isaacs and Lyon, 2000; Brauner and Loprest, 1999; Loprest, 1999).
Employment and Earnings. The majority of leavers are working, with employment rates in the first quarter after exit ranging from 50 percent to 75 percent. Continuous leavers, or those who were still off welfare by the time of the follow-up survey, had somewhat higher employment rates than the full group of leavers. Although most were employed, their average earnings were fairly low—about $1,000 per month.
Benefit Receipt. About a third of the leavers had returned to welfare at some point within the first year after exit. Among all leavers, the use of non-welfare benefits is generally lower than would be expected, given that most of them probably remain eligible for benefits. Medicaid enrollment falls after exit; in the quarter after exit, enrollment rates in most studies ranged from 35 percent to 60 percent. Only about 40 percent to 60 percent of leavers stayed on Food Stamps after exit.
Income/Material Hardship. Most families are still struggling economically after they leave welfare, and a fair number report facing various hardships, such as problems providing enough food or paying rent. Average household income, as measured on the surveys, ranged from $1,050 to $1,400. In the two studies that calculated a poverty rate, 58 percent of leavers had incomes below the poverty level. On the other hand, a few state studies asked leavers to compare their well-being before and after welfare, and the majority of respondents reported that they were better off after having left welfare. Some of the studies also compare the leavers with current recipients in order to put their economic status into context. The results are mixed: In some states, leavers were worse off than current recipients; in other states, they were better off (Isaacs and Lyon, 2000). Using the NSAF data, Loprest and Zedlewski (1999) found few differences between leavers and stayers in terms of economic hardship. Finally, Loprest (1999) compared leavers with low-income single mothers who had not received welfare in the two years prior to the survey; the leavers faced consistently higher rates of hardship than these other low-income women.
Outcomes also differ depending on the reason the family leaves welfare. People who leave because they receive a sanction, for example, generally have lower employment rates than other leavers (Brauner and Loprest, 1999). People who leave because of reaching a time limit have also been compared with other leavers (see Bloom et al., 2002, for a review). The two groups tend to have similar post-exit employment rates, and time-limit leavers are more likely to receive non-welfare benefits, such as Medicaid and Food Stamps. The evidence from several state studies does not tell a consistent story about whether time-limit leavers fare worse economically than other leavers.
It is important to note that these studies do not show causation. People who leave welfare may be better or worse off than those who stay, or better or worse off than other low-income women, but this does not prove that leaving welfare led to that outcome. Gauging the effects of leaving welfare requires knowing the counterfactual, or how these families would have fared had they stayed on welfare.
Another line of research examines whether people who left more recently are worse off economically than those who left several years ago. If the “get tough” message and practice of welfare reform pushed more and more families off welfare who are less equipped to work, then leavers in recent years may be worse off and more disadvantaged than the leavers of the mid- or early 1990s. Although most leavers at a given point in time are struggling economically, there is little evidence to suggest that more recent leavers are worse off. The study in Cuyahoga County, for example, found that people who left welfare in 1998 were more likely to work and more likely to work consistently than those who left in 1996 (Verma and Colton, 2001). There were also few differences in their demographic characteristics. Loprest (2001) compared leavers from the two waves of the NSAF and found that the two groups look fairly similar in terms of demographic characteristics and employment rates. The picture in terms of economic well-being was less clear. Although fewer of the recent leavers were below poverty, more of them reported economic struggles with respect to buying food and paying rent.
Stayers
The other side of the caseload decline concerns stayers, or those who are left on the welfare rolls. As mentioned earlier, the research consistently finds that people who stay on welfare are more disadvantaged, on average, than people who leave. They are less educated, for example, and have less work experience. An important question with respect to stayers is whether they have become increasingly harder-to-employ in recent years. The dramatic decline in the caseload may have been driven by the people who can leave welfare most easily, or those who are the most employable. In this case, the current caseload, or people receiving welfare today, is likely to be more disadvantaged and to face more barriers to work than the caseload in 1994, for example. On the other hand, if the caseload decline occurred among all types of recipients, not just the most employable, the current caseload may not be more disadvantaged than the caseload several years earlier. There is less research on this question, but the evidence does not point to big differences between current and past recipients. Zedlewski and Anderson (2001) compare people who were receiving welfare in 1997 with those who were receiving welfare in 1999. Although the two groups look different in some ways (the more recent caseload, for example, has a higher percentage of women living with a partner and a higher percentage of black women), the recent caseload did not look more disadvantaged. In fact, more parents in the recent caseload were working at the time of the survey. Oellerich (2001) uses AFDC quality control data from 1988 to 1999 and also finds little evidence that the caseload has become harder-to-employ.
In sum, people who leave welfare are less disadvantaged and face fewer barriers to work than people who stay. Most leavers work after they leave welfare, although not necessarily consistently. Many leavers do not receive other benefits for which they are probably eligible, and most are still poor. Finally, the caseload does not seem to have changed in a substantial way; recent leavers are not more disadvantaged than earlier leavers, and the caseload has not become filled with the ranks of the hardest-to employ. The last finding suggests that, although leavers are more employable than stayers on average, a fairly broad cross-section of the caseload left welfare over the past several years and also that a broad cross-section - including new entrants to welfare - continues to receive benefits.
This study adds to the research in several ways. First, it offers administrative records data on welfare receipt for between three and five years for each sample member. It uses these data to track patterns of receipt over time and to identify long-term leavers, long-term stayers, and others who cycle on and off welfare. In the existing research, leavers are defined very broadly to include people who may come back on the rolls fairly quickly. Would the results differ if the definition were changed to include only people who have left for a longer time? For example, the research shows that leavers are less disadvantaged than stayers. Are these differences bigger when long-term stayers and long-term leavers are compared? And would the same conclusions be reached about how leavers are faring if this long-term definition were used? This study also examines the characteristics and circumstances of cyclers, a group that has received less attention in the research.
Second, this study uses administrative data on employment and earnings to track employment at the point of exit and beyond for welfare leavers. These data identify a key group of interest to policymakers—nonworking welfare leavers—and examine their characteristics and circumstances after exiting welfare. Who are the people who left welfare with no apparent work? What income sources do they rely on and how do the fare relative to workers?
Finally, this study takes advantage of the variation in welfare-to-work programs to examine whether the characteristics and circumstances of welfare leavers and stayers differ by program type. For example, do time-limit programs result in different types of people leaving welfare than other programs, thus affecting how leavers look and fare relative to stayers?
Data and Methods
Data
The data used in this report come from several programs that have been evaluated by MDRC. Each of the programs was evaluated using a random assignment design, in which ongoing recipients or new applicants to welfare were assigned to either an experimental group that received the new treatment or a control group that was subject to the existing welfare system in the state at the time of the evaluation. New applicants for welfare were randomly assigned at the time they were applying for welfare, whereas ongoing recipients were randomly assigned at their redetermination interviews.1
Each evaluation provides three data sources. First, demographic data—including age, race, and education level—were collected for all sample members at the point of random assignment, or baseline. Second, state administrative records data provide information on quarterly earnings, monthly welfare receipt, and monthly Food Stamp receipt. The earnings data come from each state’s Unemployment Insurance (UI) system, to which most employers must report employee earnings. The welfare and Food Stamp data come from each state’s welfare records. One limitation of these data is that they do not capture earnings or benefit receipt for recipients who have moved out of state. Third, each evaluation administered a survey to a subset of the sample about two to three years after random assignment. The surveys capture employment and earnings not reported to the UI system, and they also provide more detailed information on family well-being, including household composition, income, income sources, material hardship, and barriers to employment.
Data from the following programs are used in the report:
Vermont’s Welfare Restructuring Project (WRP). Vermont’s Welfare Restructur-ing Project was one of the first statewide welfare reform programs initiated under waivers of federal welfare rules. WRP was implemented in July 1994 and ran through June 2001. The program consisted of a 30-month work trigger that required most single parents to work once they had received welfare for 30 cumulative months. The program also included financial incentives in the form of an enhanced disregard that was somewhat more generous than under Vermont’s old AFDC program. A three-group research design, in which some individuals received only the enhanced incentives without the work trigger, was included as part of the evaluation to compare the effects of incentives alone with the effects of incentives combined with the work trigger. The evaluation sample includes over 12,000 people from six of Vermont’s 12 welfare districts, who were randomly assigned from 1994 to 1996. Administrative data are available from 1992 to 1998, and a survey administered three and a half years after random assignment is available for a subset of the sample.
The full WRP program produced modest increases in employment during the follow-up period prior to the work trigger and had little effect on rates of welfare receipt. The WRP Incentives Only program had little impact on employment rates and modestly increased welfare receipt. An increase in welfare receipt is somewhat expected from an incentives program, since incentives allow recipients to remain eligible for benefits at a higher level of earnings. See Bloom, Michalopoulos, Walter, and Auspos (1998) for details on WRP’s interim effects.
The Minnesota Family Investment Program (MFIP). MFIP tested the effects of astrategy that combined financial incentives to work—in the form of enhanced earnings disregards relative to the AFDC system - and mandated participation in work-focused activities. MFIP also sought to simplify the calculation and receipt of benefits: Recipients in the MFIP group had their Food Stamp benefits “cashed-out,” meaning that they received them as part of their MFIP check. The sample consists of over 13,000 families randomly assigned between 1994 and 1996, for whom administrative records data are available from 1993 to 1998. A subset of the sample was given a survey three years after they entered the program.
The full MFIP program led to fairly large increases in employment for long-term recipients and more modest increases for recent applicants. The program also increased welfare receipt because of its more generous disregards. As a result of higher employment and welfare benefits, people in the program group had higher incomes than their control group counterparts. The MFIP Incentives Only program, in contrast, modestly increased employment rates and led to somewhat larger increases in welfare receipt. See Knox, Miller, and Gennetian (2000) for a summary of MFIP’s effects.
The National Evaluation of Welfare-to-Work Strategies (NEWWS). NEWWS was a test of Job Opportunities and Basic Skills (JOBS) programs across seven sites in six states. The evaluation provided a test of employment-focused services, in which recipients were placed in employment-related activities and encouraged to find jobs relatively quickly, and education-focused services, which had a greater focus on skill-building prior to entering the workforce. The sample for NEWWS consists of over 44,000 single-parent families randomly assigned between 1991 and 1994, for whom administrative records data are available from 1989 through 1997, although this varies somewhat across sites. This report uses data from a survey given to a subset of the sample two years after they entered the evaluation.
Most of the NEWWS employment-focused programs increased employment, and some had larger effects than others. Portland, Oregon, for example, produced the largest employment impacts among the NEWWS programs. Most programs also reduced welfare receipt, and the size of the welfare impacts tended to mirror the size of the employment and earnings impacts. The education-focused programs generally had smaller impacts on employment than the employment-focused programs, with two sites (Oklahoma and Detroit) showing very small or no impacts. Although the programs increased employment and earnings, they did not increase incomes, since for most recipients the increase in earnings was offset by a reduction in benefits. See Hamilton (2002) for more information on the effects of NEWWS programs.
Florida’s Family Transition Program (FTP). FTP tested the effects of 24- and 36-month time limits on welfare receipt for a sample of 2,800 single-parent families in Escambia County, Florida. The program, which started in 1994, offered financial incentives as well as enhanced services designed to help recipients find jobs. Administrative records data are available for each sample member from 1992 through 1999. A subset of the sample was given a survey four years after program entry. Families were randomly assigned into the program between 1994 and 1995.
FTP increased employment and reduced welfare receipt, and the majority of those in the program group left welfare before reaching their time limit. Most of the recipients who did reach a time limit were not given extensions: About 40 percent had adequate earnings levels that did not warrant an extension, while most of the rest were deemed noncompliant. The leavers whose benefits were cancelled because they had reached a time limit were somewhat more disadvantaged than other leavers, but they did not, on average, experience more hardship, partly because they relied more on other sources of support. See Bloom et al. (2000) for the final report on FTP’s effects.
Connecticut’s Jobs First Program. Jobs First evaluated the effects of a 21-month Connecticut’s Jobs First Program.time limit on welfare receipt in the offices of Manchester and New Haven (although the
program was run statewide). The program also included very generous financial incentives to encourage work: All of a recipient’s earnings were disregarded when calculating her grant level and Food Stamp benefits until her earnings reached the poverty line. The sample includes about 4,800 people randomly assigned in 1996 and early 1997. A subset of the full sample also responded to a 36-month survey. Administrative records data for this evaluation cover the period 1994 through 1999.
Jobs First increased employment and earnings throughout the four-year follow-up period. During the early part of follow-up—before recipients began reaching time limits - the program also increased welfare receipt and, because of the generous disregards, increased incomes. About half the recipients in the program group reached the time limit during the period, and two-thirds of them subsequently received a six-month extension. Those who left welfare because of a time limit had higher earnings than those who left earlier, most likely because of the extension policy. See Bloom et al. (2002) for more information about Jobs First.
1About 10 percent of the sample used in this report were in a two-parent family when they entered the evaluation. The results did not differ when these sample members were excluded from the analysis.
Samples
For the analysis in this report, the samples in each program are restricted to people for whom data were available for at least 36 months but no more than 60 months after they were randomly assigned into a program. The evaluations have varying lengths of follow-up, and this restriction is imposed so that “staying on welfare” and “leaving welfare” mean something similar across programs. Some people in NEWWS, for example, are followed for up to six years after random assignment, while people in MFIP are tracked only for four years.
Table 1 presents the sample sizes, by project, for the full administrative records sample and the smaller survey sample. The full sample is used for analyses of demographic characteris-tics and potential barriers to work, and the survey sample is used for analyses of survey2 outcomes, including household income, household composition, and material hardship.Each analysis was run for the pooled sample and then for each program separately, and the pooled analyses were weighted to reflect the size of the state’s welfare caseload in the mid-1990s. Although the data are weighted, the sample should not be considered a representative sample of the recipient population in these states, owing to the idiosyncrasies of the evaluations. Some programs, for example, oversampled new applicants relative to ongoing recipients, while others screened out exempt individuals prior to random assignment. In addition, each of the evaluations operated in selected counties within the state involved.
When the programs are analyzed individually, they are presented in an order that roughly corresponds with the strength of their mandate to leave welfare. The first group is incentives only and includes the two programs that used enhanced financial incentives relative to the traditional AFDC program but did not impose any work requirements (WRP Incentives Only and MFIP Incentives Only). The second group includes programs that combined financial incentives with a work requirement (the full WRP program and the full MFIP program). The third group includes traditional welfare-to-work programs that did not use financial incentives but that encouraged recipients to leave welfare either by offering them education-focused services (NEWWS, education-focused) or employment-focused services (NEWWS, employment-focused). The final group includes the two time-limit programs, both of which also offered enhanced financial incentives (Jobs First and FTP).
Most analyses in the report are restricted to people in the program (or experimental) groups in each evaluation. These are the most relevant groups, since members were subject to the reforms being tested, many of which are key elements of states’ new TANF programs. In addition, results are presented for a pooled sample - combining data from each evaluation - and for each evaluation separately. The control groups are used only toward the end of the report, when the program and control groups are compared in order to infer the effects of the particular program being tested.
Table 1
Sample Sizes, by Program
SOURCE: Data from MDRC evaluations of the following programs:
WRP (Vermont's Welfare Restructuring Project)
MFIP (Minnesota's Family Investment Program)
NEWWS (National Evaluation of Welfare-to-Work Strategies)
Jobs First (Connecticut's Welfare Reform Initiative)
FTP (Family Transition Program)
2The results using the full sample to compare demographic characteristics and barriers to work were similar when restricted to the smaller survey sample.
Defining Leavers, Stayers, and Cyclers
The definition of “leaving welfare” varies across the studies in the existing research. In order to compare results across states, most of the HHS-sponsored leaver studies use the traditional “two-months-off” definition. Recipients who, during the period studied, were observed to be off welfare for at least two consecutive months were defined as “leavers.” This two-month minimum is used to avoid one-month breaks in payments that sometimes occur because of administrative errors. A few of these studies also define “continuous leavers” as those who were still off welfare at the time of the follow-up survey, which ranged from six months to three years after their exit. Studies using the Urban Institute’s NSAF, on the other hand, define leavers as those who had received benefits at some point during the two years prior to the survey but were not receiving benefits at the time of the survey.
This report uses a stricter definition of leaving in order to focus on those women who were fairly reliant on welfare at some point during the period but then really left, meaning that they left welfare and stayed off for at least 12 consecutive months. This definition of leavers follows Moffitt and Roff (2000), who define a group called “dependency leavers,” or people who leave relatively long spells of welfare and stay off for a substantial amount of time. They found that only about half the conventionally defined leavers were dependency leavers.
Although defining leavers using the “two-months-off” criterion has its merits (it is important to determine how long leavers stay off welfare, for example, and who eventually returns), a stricter definition of leaving may be more policy-relevant, in the sense that it focuses on families who have really left welfare. Similarly, this report uses a stricter definition of “staying.” Rather than examining people who were receiving benefits at the time of the survey (which will include people who recently came onto welfare and people who will leave in a few months), stayers are defined as those recipients who stayed on welfare for nearly the entire3.Again, this distinction may be most relevant for policymakers and state follow-up period.administrators as they consider policies to work with families who are left on the caseload. Of course, it is an open question whether these stricter definitions will tell a noticeably different story from the traditional definitions. This report helps to answer whether this distinction matters and, if so, in what ways.
The three groups are defined as follows:
- Leavers. People who received welfare for at least 6 consecutive months and subsequently left and stayed off welfare for at least 12 consecutive months. Over 80 percent of leavers had only one welfare spell during the follow-up period.
-
Stayers. People who never left welfare during the follow-up period or who had multiple welfare spells but spent the majority of the follow-up period on welfare. Over 70 percent of stayers had only one welfare spell and stayed on welfare throughout the entire follow-up period or left a few months before the end of the follow-up period. Most of the remaining stayers had two spells of welfare and received welfare for at least 70 percent of the follow-up period.
-
Cyclers. People who had only one spell on welfare that was six months or less or who had multiple spells but did not spend the majority of the follow-up period on welfare. One-third of cyclers had only one spell that lasted less than six months. The remainder had two or more spells of welfare but spent less than 70 percent of the follow-up period on welfare.
The cycler group—defined as everyone who did not fit the definition of a stayer or a leaver—contains a fairly diverse group of people, from those who used welfare for only a few4 Table 2 presents the percentage of leavers, months to those who cycled back on several times.stayers, and cyclers for the pooled sample and for each of the programs. About one-third of the total sample are defined as stayers, 48.1 percent are leavers, and 20.2 percent are cyclers. This pattern varies across the programs in expected ways. For example, stayers make up a higher fraction of the MFIP samples, since MFIP’s generous financial incentives allowed recipients to work and still remain eligible for some benefits. Although the WRP program also had incentives, they were much less generous than MFIP’s. FTP, one of the time-limit programs, has the fewest stayers. Although Jobs First also had a time limit, two factors might account for the relatively high fraction of stayers in the sample. First, extensions to the time limit were typically granted to recipients who were not earning above a certain amount. Second, although the sample in all evaluations is restricted to people with between 36 and 60 months of follow-up data, the follow-up period for the Jobs First sample is on the short end of this range, meaning that there were fewer months to observe recipients leaving welfare. Many recipients in the NEWWS sample, in contrast, were followed for up to 60 months, which may partly explain why there are fewer stayers in NEWWS than in Jobs First.
Table 2
Patterns of Receipt, by Program
SOURCE: MDRC calculations from administrative records.
3The length of the follow-up varies across evaluations, ranging from 36 to 60 months.
4As discussed later, the results did not differ significantly when the cycler group was restricted to people with at least two welfare spells.
Leavers, Stayers, and Cyclers
Characteristics
Table 3 presents characteristics of the three groups for the pooled sample. The top panel presents several demographic characteristics, and the bottom panel presents data relating to employment prospects. The first three columns present data for the three groups, and the last two columns show the differences between the groups. Differences that are marked with asterisks are statistically significant. A difference between two groups that is statistically significant is likely to represent a true difference between the groups, rather than one that has arisen by chance.
Focusing first on the differences between stayers and leavers, the data show that stayers are relatively more disadvantaged. Stayers are somewhat younger than leavers; they are less educated (54.7 percent of stayers did not complete high school, compared with only 46.9 percent of leavers), and they are more likely to have young children. A higher fraction of stayers are black or Hispanic, compared with leavers, and a higher fraction are never-married.
These differences are perhaps not surprising, since many of these characteristics are strongly tied to a recipient’s ability to find and keep a job. Education level is an important predictor of labor market success, for example, and young children may prevent work if mothers cannot find or afford adequate child care. The bottom panel of the table presents data on several potential barriers to employment. In every evaluation except Jobs First, sample members were asked a series of questions at random assignment about their attitudes and opinions about welfare and work. Three of the questions concerned child care problems, transportation problems, and health or emotional problems that prevented respondents from working. Stayers were more likely than leavers to report problems with each of these factors, with the biggest difference for child care: 69.2 percent of stayers reported that they could not work at random assignment due to problems arranging child care, compared with 58.9 percent of leavers. Stayers were also less likely to have worked in the year prior to random assignment. Prior work experience is an important predictor of subsequent employment.
Table 3
Stayers, Cyclers, and Leavers:
Demographic Characteristics and Barriers to Employment
SOURCE: MDRC calculations from administrative records, Baseline Information Forms and Private Opinion Surveys from the evaluations listed in Table 1.
NOTES: The analysis is restricted to the individuals in the Program Group.
The data are weighted to reflect the size of the welfare caseload in each state.
Although the existence of any one of these barriers hinders the ability to find work, previous research has found that the total number of barriers is also important (Danziger et al., 1999). In other words, barriers add up, in the sense that facing several of them (such as low education combined with child care problems) severely limits employment prospects. The bottom several rows of Table 3 present data on the sum of seven potential barriers to work:5 child care problems, transportation problems, health or emotional problems, lack of work in the year prior to random assignment, lack of a high school diploma, the presence of children under age 6, and the presence of two or more children. Not surprisingly, stayers are much more likely to have several barriers; 37.9 percent of stayers had five or more of these barriers, compared with 25.9 percent of leavers. What is striking, however, is the high number of stayers and leavers with multiple barriers; 62.0 percent of stayers and 46.0 percent of leavers faced four or more potential barriers to work.
The second column of Table 3 presents data for cyclers, and the last column presents differences between cyclers and leavers. Although most of the differences in demographic characteristics between cyclers and leavers are statically significant, few of them are big. In other words, cyclers look fairly similar to leavers. For example, there is virtually no difference in education levels and marital status between the two groups. However, there are more noticeable differences in potential barriers to work. Cyclers are less likely than leavers and stayers to report each of the barriers, particularly the lack of prior work experience. This is not surprising, given the way in which the groups are defined. As noted above, about a third of the cyclers had only one short spell of welfare. In contrast, leavers were defined as people who spent at least six months on welfare before exiting.
Separate analyses examined the characteristics of a cycler group, referred to as “long-term cyclers,” that did not include people who had only one short spell on welfare. The results are fairly similar to those presented in Table 3. The long-term cyclers were slightly more likely than all cyclers to report certain barriers to employment, but, on average, they still looked much more like leavers than stayers.
5Health or emotional problems are defined very broadly, using individuals’ responses to a question about the reasons they are not working at random assignment. “Health or emotional problems” was listed as a possible response.
Economic Status
Table 4 uses the survey samples to present data on family income and material hardship, measured at the time of the follow-up surveys. The top panel presents income and poverty in the month before the survey and household composition at the time of the survey. The bottompanel presents several measures of material hardship, experienced either during the 12 months prior to the survey or, in the case of food hardship, in the month prior to the survey. Note that because leavers, stayers, and cyclers were defined using the administrative records data, some leavers report receiving welfare income in the month prior to the survey, because they had returned to welfare by that time.6
Table 4
Stayers, Cyclers, and Leavers:
Household Income and Material Hardship
SOURCE: MDRC calculations from survey data from the evaluations listed in Table 1.
NOTES: This analysis is restricted to the individuals in the Program Group.
The data are weighted to reflect the size of the welfare caseload in each state.
The first row of Table 4 presents total household income, measured as the sum of all income sources for the family in the prior month. Average incomes—ranging from $1,200 to $1,500—are quite low for all three groups. On average, leavers had higher incomes than stayers, although the difference is not big: $1,517 compared with $1,237. As mentioned in the previous section, this difference in incomes does not prove causation, or that leaving welfare made these families better off. Because leavers were less disadvantaged than stayers, it is likely that they would have had higher incomes even if they had not left welfare. In fact, the formal evaluations of many welfare-to-work programs, including those used for this report, suggest that leaving welfare does not make many families better off; programs that encouraged families to leave welfare did not, on average, lead to increases in income.
The next two rows of Table 4 present data on poverty and severe poverty. The poverty rate is calculated by comparing an annualized measure of income in the month prior to the survey with the official poverty rate for each family. It is not comparable to the official poverty rate, because it is based on monthly income and because it counts Food Stamp benefits as part of income. It is also based on pretax income and does not subtract payroll taxes or add any benefits that the family might receive from the Earned Income Tax Credit (EITC).
Despite the small difference in average incomes for leavers and stayers, leavers had a much lower poverty rate; 61.3 percent of stayers were below poverty, compared with 42.7 percent of leavers. This difference between income and poverty suggests that many of the people who left welfare had incomes just above the poverty line. Despite having a lower overall poverty rate, leavers were somewhat more likely than stayers to have incomes below 50.0 percent of the poverty line, or to be in severe poverty. Although this difference is small, it shows that some fraction of families did not fare well after leaving welfare. Stayers were much more likely than leavers to rely on welfare and Food Stamps as income sources and were much less likely to rely on their own earnings or the earnings of other adults in the household. The low rate of Food Stamp use among leavers is consistent with findings from other research, showing that many families who leave welfare do not stay on Food Stamps even though they are probably still eligible for them. The low take-up rate is thought to be due to a variety of factors, such as a lack of information on eligibility and the time and money hassles of applying and reapplying for benefits (Miller, Redcross, and Henrichson, 2002).
The next several rows of Table 4 present data on household composition. Less then 10 percent of the parents in the sample were married at the time of the survey, and about 15 percent to 20 percent had other nonspouse adults in the household. The differences in household composition between stayers and leavers are not large, although they are consistent with the idea that some people left welfare not for work but for marriage or cohabitation. Leavers were somewhat more likely than stayers to be married at the time of the survey and, if they were not married, to have other adults in the household. Consistent with Table 3, cyclers look very similar to leavers in terms of income and household composition.
The last several rows of Table 4 present data on material hardship. Respondents were asked whether they had experienced any of the listed hardships in the year prior to the survey. A glance at the numbers for all three groups indicates a fairly high rate of economic struggles; about a third of respondents did not pay their full rent at some point, and a similar number had their telephones disconnected. Despite having higher incomes and lower poverty rates, both leavers and cyclers reported greater levels of material hardship than stayers. The biggest differences are in access to health care. Leavers and cyclers were much more likely to report that there was someone in their household who needed to go to a doctor (or go to a hospital) or dentist but could not go. For example, 23.3 percent of leavers reported that they could not see a doctor, compared with only 8.8 percent of stayers. This difference is an important one and is most likely related to the loss of Medicaid when families leave welfare. Many families who leave welfare lose health coverage, despite the existence of transitional Medicaid and other health programs for low-income families (Quint and Widom, 2001).
The last row of Table 4 examines food hardship. Respondents were asked to describe the household’s food eaten in the month prior to the survey. Those who responded “Sometimes not enough to eat” or “Often not enough to eat” are defined as food-insufficient. Stayers and cyclers had somewhat higher rates of food insufficiency than leavers, but the differences are not large.
How would these results differ if welfare leavers had been defined in the same way as in the earlier studies—meaning all recipients who left welfare for at least two consecutive months during the follow-up period? Using this definition, about 80 percent of the sample are leavers, which includes all cyclers and nearly half the people who were previously defined as stayers. Appendix Tables A1 and A2 present the results comparing traditionally defined leavers with the remaining 20 percent of the sample (which, by definition, includes only those people who never left welfare for at least two consecutive months). In general, the results are similar. For example, leavers are more educated than stayers; they have fewer children; and they are less likely to be black. The results are also similar for prior work experience and employment barriers. Table A2 presents income and material hardship. Leavers have higher incomes than stayers and are much less likely to be poor. The group of traditionally defined leavers has a somewhat higher poverty rate than the long-term leavers (see Table 4), but the difference is not large. Thus, although the longer-term definitions may be theoretically more precise in identifying groups of interest, in practice they seem to have few implications for describing the average characteristics of various groups in the caseload. Part of the reason for this finding is that cyclers look, on average, very similar to leavers.
6A small number of leavers may have not yet left welfare by the time of the survey.
Results for Individual Programs
The results for the pooled sample show that leavers are less disadvantaged than stayers, which is consistent with other research. Leavers are more educated, face fewer barriers to work, and have somewhat higher incomes. All the leavers left welfare as part of a welfare-to-work program, but some left under a program with financial incentives, and others left under time limits. Does the type of welfare program affect who leaves versus who stays and how leavers fare relative to stayers?
The extent to which leavers differ from stayers in any given program depends on who is encouraged to leave or stay. If the program moves a fairly broad cross-section of recipients off the rolls, then leavers may be fairly similar to stayers. On the other hand, if only the most employable recipients leave, then the leavers might look very different from the average stayer. In programs with incentives (but without time limits), most of the people who leave welfare may be those whose earnings are high enough that they lose eligibility. In this case, leavers may look very different from stayers. At the other extreme is time limits, which may encourage a broader group of recipients to leave welfare, depending on how the time limit is administered. In FTP, for example, few extensions were granted to people who reached the limit, whereas in Jobs First extensions were typically granted if the recipient’s earnings were not high enough.
Figure 1A presents selected characteristics of the three groups for each program. The programs are ordered by type: incentives only (WRP IO, MFIP IO); incentives plus mandates (WRP, MFIP); education-focused without incentives (NEWWS ED); employment-focused without incentives (NEWWS EMP); and time limits with incentives (Jobs First and FTP). With a few exceptions, the patterns found for the full sample hold for each individual program. For example, stayers across each program are less likely than their leaver counterparts to have completed high school, with the biggest differences being found in MFIP and FTP. Stayers are also more likely than leavers in each program to have two or more children. The differences by race also hold up across each program; a higher fraction of stayers than leavers are black, with the biggest difference appearing in FTP. In general, cyclers look more like leavers than stayers in each program, particularly in terms of education levels.
Figure 1B shows several potential barriers to employment. (Data on several key barriers are not available for Connecticut’s Jobs First program.) Again, the overall pattern found for the pooled sample is also found for each program. Stayers in each program are more likely than leavers to report problems with child care and with transportation. The relatively high levels of reported child care problems for the NEWWS sample may be due to the fact that the evaluation took place several years earlier than the other programs. Funding for child care assistance has greatly increased since the early 1990s. Stayers are also less likely to have worked in the year prior to random assignment, except in the MFIP Incentives Only and the two time-limit programs. Finally, in all programs except FTP, stayers are more likely to have four or more barriers to work.
Figure 1C presents data on income and material hardship. (Not all hardship measures are available from every survey.) For these outcomes, there is more variation across programs in terms of overall levels and in terms of differences between stayers and leavers. For example, stayers had the highest monthly incomes and the lowest poverty rates in the two MFIP programs and Jobs First—the programs with the most generous financial incentives. Although FTP included enhanced incentives along with time limits, welfare benefits are relatively low in Florida, so that a fairly high fraction of stayers were below poverty.
Stayers in all programs had lower incomes than leavers, and the differences were largest in the two MFIP programs. This pattern is consistent with the idea that people who left welfare in these programs were those whose earnings were high enough to make them ineligible. The results are different for poverty rates. Although the biggest income differences between leavers and stayers were found in MFIP, this program, along with Jobs First, had the smallest differences in poverty. Although this seems counterintuitive, the incentives in both these programs allowed recipients to combine work and welfare until their income was above the poverty line. Thus, many stayers in these programs were already above the poverty line.
Figures 1B and 1C present material hardship and food sufficiency. Leavers and cyclers report higher numbers of hardships in three of the four programs with available data, and the biggest differences are for the time-limit programs. In most of the programs, stayers are more likely to report being food-insufficient, although the differences are generally small.
Figure 1A
Stayers, Cyclers, and Leavers, by Program:
Demographic Characteristics
Percent younger than 25
Percent completed high school
Percent black
Percent with two or more children
SOURCE: MDRC calculations from administrative records and Baseline Information Forms
from the evaluations listed in Table 1.
NOTES: The analysis is restricted to the individuals in the Program Group.
Figure 1B
Stayers, Cyclers, and Leavers, by Program:
Barriers to Employment
Percent with problems arranging child care
Percent with transportation problems
Percent who did not work in year
prior to random assignment
Percent with four or more
barriers to employment
SOURCE: MDRC calculations from administrative records and Private Opinion Surveys from the evaluations listed in Table 1.
NOTES: The analysis is restricted to the individuals in the Program Group.
Figure 1C
Stayers, Cyclers, and Leavers, by Program:
Household Income and Material Hardship
Income in month before survey
Percent below poverty in month before survey
Number of Hardships
Percent with Food Insufficiency
SOURCE: MDRC calculations from survey data from the evaluations listed in Table 1.
NOTES: This analysis is restricted to the individuals in the Program Group.
The results by program suggest that the type of welfare program does not have much influence on the ways in which leavers differ from stayers, at least with respect to demographic characteristics and employment barriers. For example, one hypothesis raised earlier was that leavers in incentives programs would look very different from stayers. And although leavers in these programs were more educated and had fewer employment barriers than stayers, these differences were not any bigger or more prevalent than in the time-limit or nonincentive programs. The incentives programs did, however, show larger differences in incomes between the two groups.
Time Limits
Looking across Figures 1A, 1B, and 1C, there are several instances where the results for FTP seem to stand out. Leavers in FTP were younger than stayers (in contrast to each of the other programs), and they were much more likely to have completed high school (a difference that was the largest among the programs). Yet the leavers and the stayers did not differ much in terms of employment barriers (in contrast to most other programs). In some ways, then, leavers look more employable than stayers, but, in other ways, they do not. This pattern suggests that it might be interesting to divide leavers in FTP into those who left welfare because of reaching the time limit (a group that is likely to be relatively disadvantaged) and those who left welfare before reaching the time limit (a group that may look more like the typical leaver in the other programs). Although the Jobs First time-limit policy differed in important ways from FTP’s, similar data are also presented for Jobs First.
Tables 5 and 6 present the results. This distinction between time-limit and non-time-limit leavers seems to matter the most in FTP. Time-limit leavers in FTP are less educated and have more children than non-time-limit leavers, for example, and a higher fraction of them are black. Although time-limit leavers are less likely to report barriers to work in terms of child care, transportation, and health or emotional problems, they are much less likely than the other two groups to have worked prior to random assignment. They are also more likely than both stayers and non-time-limit leavers to have four or more barriers to work (56.9 percent for time-limit leavers, versus 46.5 percent for non-time-limit leavers and 50.0 percent for stayers).
The results are similar for Jobs First but are not as pronounced or consistent. Although a higher fraction of time-limit leavers are black and living in public housing, for example, they are just as likely as non-time-limit leavers to have completed high school and are more likely to have worked in the year prior to random assignment. Thus, the more employable recipients appear to have left because of a time limit in Jobs First. This finding makes sense given the extension policy, in which recipients who reached the limit without sufficiently high earnings were typically granted extensions. Few extensions were granted in FTP.
Table 5
Stayers, Time Limit Leavers, and Non-Time Limit Leavers (FTP and Jobs First):
Demographic Characteristics and Barriers to Employment
SOURCE: MDRC calculations from administrative records, Baseline Information Forms and Private Opinion Surveys
from FTP and Jobs First.
NOTES: The analysis is restricted to the individuals in the Program Group.
Table 6
Stayers, Time Limit Leavers, and
Non-Time Limit Leavers (FTP):
Household Income and Material Hardship
SOURCE: MDRC calculations from survey data from FTP.
NOTES: This analysis is restricted to the individuals in the Program Group.
Table 6 presents income and material hardship data for FTP. (These results should be interpreted with some caution, given the small sample sizes. Data for Jobs First are not presented because the sample is too small.) Time-limit leavers have lower incomes and higher poverty rates than other leavers, but they are not much worse off than stayers. Thus, they appear to have partially made up for the loss in welfare benefits with other sources of income. For example, 73.8 percent of time-limit leavers received Food Stamps, and 46.0 percent received child support income. The data on household composition suggest that time-limit leavers may have also moved in with other adults after losing benefits; 42.2 percent of them were living with other nonspouse adults.
Despite having lower incomes, time-limit leavers report similar levels of material hard-ship as other leavers, and they are less likely to be food-insufficient. Nonetheless, the data on poverty rates suggest that some time-limit leavers are not faring well; 33.8 percent of them had incomes below 50.0 percent of the poverty line, compared with 24.1 percent for other leavers. Again, the results should be interpreted with some caution, given the small sample sizes.
Nonworking Leavers
The results so far show that the average welfare leaver faced fewer barriers to employment than the average stayer and, as of the follow-up survey, had somewhat higher income. But what about leavers who are not “average”? Focusing on the average may mask the fact that many people who leave welfare do not fare well. The previous section showed, for example, that half of leavers did not work in the year prior to random assignment; almost half faced four or more potential barriers to work; and about 40 percent had incomes below the poverty line. This section focuses on a group that may not fare well after leaving and one that has been the subject of growing concern—people who are not working when they leave welfare.
Table 7 presents information on employment among leavers. Work status is defined using administrative records data. A potential limitation of these data is that they miss employment for some low-wage workers and for people who work out of state. About one-third of the7 leavers did not work in the first few months after their welfare exit.7 Among this group, only 16 percent were working in month 12 after their exit. In contrast, among those who did work in the first few months after leaving welfare, 79 percent were also working in month 12. This pattern suggests that work status at the point of leaving welfare is a good predictor of longer-term employment. Thus, for the following analyses, nonworkers are defined as leavers who did not work in the first few months after exit.
Table 7
Patterns of Work Among Welfare Leavers
SOURCE: MDRC calculations from administrative records from the evaluations listed in Table 1.
NOTES: This analysis is restricted to the individuals in the Program Group.
The data are weighted to reflect the size of the welfare caseload in each state.
Characteristics
Table 8 presents demographic characteristics and employment barriers for working and nonworking welfare leavers. A glance through the differences shows that nonworkers are, not surprisingly, more disadvantaged than workers; 55.0 percent of nonworkers do not have a high school diploma, compared with only 40.9 percent of workers. The bottom panel of the table shows the importance of prior work experience as a predictor of subsequent work; 67.7 percent of nonworkers did not work in the year prior to random assignment—a proportion that is substantially higher than for both workers (41.5 percent) and stayers (see Table 3). Nonworkers are also older than workers, and more of them have a youngest child who is age 15 or older, suggesting that more of this group lost eligibility for welfare because their children “aged-out,” or turned 18. This type of difference may not have much to do with employability, but it may have implications for how these families fare after leaving welfare.
Finally, Table 8 shows markedly different rates of Food Stamp use; 23.1 percent of nonworkers stayed on Food Stamps, compared with 42.8 percent of workers. It is not clear why take-up rates for nonworkers are so low. It may be the case that people who leave welfare without work are the most likely to lose touch with caseworkers as they exit. When recipients fail to show up for redetermination interviews, caseworkers often terminate both their cash and their Food Stamp benefits (Quint and Widom, 2001).8
Table 8
Working Leavers Versus Nonworking Leavers:
Demographic Characteristics and Barriers to Employment
SOURCE: MDRC calculations from administrative records, Baseline Information Forms and
Private Opinion Surveys from the evaluations listed in Table 1.
NOTES: The analysis is restricted to the individuals in the Program Group.
The data are weighted to reflect the size of the welfare caseload in each state.
8Alternatively, it may be the case that some of the people defined as nonworking leavers moved out of state when they left welfare. Since UI earnings records and Food Stamp data would not be available for these families, they would be defined as not working and as not receiving Food Stamps.
Economic Status
Table 9 presents data on income and material hardship. Despite some of the large differences in demographic characteristics, the two groups of leavers had similar incomes at the time of the survey, although nonworkers had a slightly higher poverty rate. Nonworkers appear to have made up for the lack of earnings with other income sources. For example, they were more likely to have returned to welfare by the time of the survey (41.8 percent versus 31.4 percent) and were9 more likely to rely on other income sources and the earnings of other adults in the household.9 Nonworkers were somewhat more likely to be married at the time of the survey, but the difference is small, which suggests that they were not more likely to leave welfare because of marriage. It is sometimes hypothesized that many people who leave welfare without apparent work have simply left for marriage or cohabitation. These data suggest otherwise. Finally, nonworkers generally reported lower levels of material hardship than workers, although more of them reported being food-insufficient.
Table 9
Working Leavers Versus Nonworking Leavers:
Household Income and Material Hardship
SOURCE: MDRC calculations from survey data from the evaluations listed in Table 1.
NOTES: This analysis is restricted to the individuals in the Program Group.
The data are weighted to reflect the size of the welfare caseload in each state.
9 The category “other income” includes pension income, disability income, and any source of income not covered by the other categories.
Results for Individual Programs
For the pooled sample, nonworking leavers are more disadvantaged than working leavers, in terms of demographic characteristics and barriers to employment. But they do not appear to be significantly worse off in terms of income and hardship, owing partly to the fact that they were more likely to have returned to welfare by the time of the survey. How do these differences vary across the welfare programs? Are nonworking recipients especially disadvantaged in the time-limit programs, for example, relative to the incentives-only programs?
As is the case with stayers versus leavers, any variation across programs in terms of workers versus nonworkers should be related to what types of people left welfare under each program and to their reasons for leaving. In a program with incentives only, for example, people who leave welfare for work may be the most employable group, since their earnings are probably high enough to make them ineligible for benefits. On the other hand, people who leave without work under such a program may leave for reasons unrelated to their employability, such as marriage or other changes in household composition. Thus, it is not obvious which program might produce the biggest differences between working and nonworking leavers. The fraction of leavers who are nonworkers is similar across the programs, ranging from a low of 32 percent in MFIP Incentives Only to a high of 38 percent in FTP.
Figure 2A presents selected characteristics of nonworking versus working leavers, by program. In several cases, the patterns found for the pooled sample also hold for the individual programs. Across all programs except Jobs First, for example, nonworking leavers are older than working leavers, or a smaller percentage are under age 25. Nonworkers are also less educated than workers in every program, with the biggest differences in MFIP Incentives Only and FTP. For race and number of children, the results are not consistent across programs, owing largely to MFIP. In both MFIP programs, nonworkers are more likely to be black and more likely to have two or more children.
The results for employment barriers are more consistent across programs (Figure 2B). In all programs, nonworkers are more likely to report barriers to work, are less likely to have worked in the year prior to random assignment, and are more likely to face four or more barriers to work. The sizes of the differences between groups are also similar across programs.
Figure 2C presents data on income and material hardship. Although the pooled results show that nonworkers had similar incomes as workers, this is not true across all programs. In MFIP Incentives Only and Jobs First, for example, nonworkers had much lower incomes than workers and were much more likely to be poor. This difference arises not because nonworkers in these programs are especially poor but because working leavers have much higher incomes than in the other programs. Again, this is consistent with the generous incentives offered in these programs, in which working recipients must earn higher amounts to become ineligible for benefits.
In sum, people who left welfare without work differ in several ways from those who left with work, and the pattern of differences is fairly consistent across programs. Although there are no clear patterns across broad program types, two programs stand out. In MFIP Incentives Only and FTP, the differences between the groups in terms of education and barriers to work are relatively large. In MFIP, the big differences may be driven by the working leavers, who are an especially employable group. In FTP, the differences may be driven by the nonworking leavers, who are especially disadvantaged. In fact, they may be the most disadvantaged: Figures 2A and 2B show that nonworking leavers in FTP have the lowest education levels of any other group in any other program and are also the most likely to have four or more barriers to work.
How Have Welfare Programs Affected the Composition of the Caseload?
Not surprisingly, people who stay on welfare persistently are different from people who leave. As discussed earlier, stayers are more likely than leavers to face a range of potential barriers to work. In this sense, long-term stayers are the most disadvantaged segment of the caseload at a point in time. One question that has arisen in the wake of welfare reform is whether the caseload has changed in recent years. As welfare reform has pushed more and more families off the rolls, has the remaining caseload become even more disadvantaged and hard to employ?
Figure 2A
Working and Nonworking Leavers, by Program:
Demographic Characteristics
Percent younger than 25
Percent completed high school
Percent black
Percent with two or more children
SOURCE: MDRC calculations from administrative records and Baseline Information forms from the evaluations listed in Table 1.
NOTES: The analysis is restricted to the individuals in the Program Group.
Figure 2B
Working and Nonworking Leavers, by Program:
Barriers to Employment
Percent with problems arranging child care
Percent with transportation problems
Percent who did not work in year prior to random assignment
Percent with four or more barriers to employment
SOURCE: MDRC calculations from administrative records and Private Opinion Surveys from the evaluations listed in Table 1.
NOTES: The analysis is restricted to the individuals in the Program Group.
Figure 2C
Working and Nonworking Leavers, by Program:
Household Income and Material Hardship
Income in month before survey
Percent below poverty in month before survey
Number of Hardships
Percent with Food Insufficiency
SOURCE: MDRC calculations from survey data from the evaluations listed in Table 1.
NOTES: This analysis is restricted to the individuals in the Program Group.
Although this report cannot address this question directly, the effects of welfare reform can be inferred by taking advantage of the experimental data from each evaluation. Stayers in the control group in each program give a picture of what the caseload would have looked like in the absence of welfare-to-work programs, since these recipients were subject to the traditional AFDC system in their state. Comparing them with stayers in the program groups—or those who were subject to the welfare-to-work program being tested—provides an estimate of how the new program affected the composition of the caseload. Note that this comparison is nonexperimental, because it is restricted to only a subset of the program and control groups.
Characteristics
Table 10 presents the demographic characteristics and barriers to employment of stayers in the program and control groups. Although the two groups of stayers look similar, a few differences suggest that program group stayers are slightly more disadvantaged than control group stayers. Stayers in the program groups are somewhat less educated than those in the control groups (54.7 percent of program group stayers did not complete high school, compared with only 49.3 percent of control group stayers), and they are slightly more likely to report health or emotional problems as barriers to employment. At the same time, however, they had more work experience during the follow-up period; they worked an average of 9.8 months during the three years after random assignment, compared with 7.4 months for stayers in the control groups. This finding is consistent with other research. Zedlewski and Anderson (2001) found that people receiving welfare in 1999 were more likely to work than those receiving welfare in 1997.
Table 10
How Programs Have Affected Stayers:
Demographic Characteristics and Barriers to Employment
SOURCE: MDRC calculations from administrative records, Baseline Information Forms and Private Opinion Surveys from the evaluations listed in Table 1.
NOTES: The data are weighted to reflect the size of the welfare caseload in each state.
Economic Status
Table 11 presents data on income and material hardship for stayers in the program and control groups. Stayers in the program groups were somewhat less likely to be poor, and they were somewhat more likely to have been working at the time of the survey; 28.3 percent of program group stayers reported earnings in the prior month, compared with 21.2 percent of control group stayers. The next section illustrates that this difference in earnings and employment is driven by the incentives programs. There are few other notable differences between the two groups of stayers.
Table 11
How Programs Have Affected Stayers:
Household Income and Material Hardship
SOURCE: MDRC calculations from survey data from the evaluations listed in Table 1.
NOTES: The data are weighted to reflect the size of the welfare caseload in each state.
Results for Individual Programs
There are several reasons to expect that the differences between stayers will differ by program. Programs with generous incentives should encourage people to stay on welfare who would have otherwise left, since they can now earn more and remain eligible for some benefits. Thus, stayers in these programs might be somewhat less disadvantaged than stayers in the control groups. They should also have higher incomes, since they can keep more of their welfare benefits while working. On the other hand, in programs that encouraged people to leave welfare, those who stayed under the program being tested might be expected to be more disadvantaged than those who stayed under the old system.
Table 12 presents each program’s effects on the percentage of the sample that stayed on welfare. As expected, the four programs with incentives but not time limits—especially the two forms of MFIP—increased the number of stayers, while the other programs reduced the number of stayers. Except for MFIP, however, the differences are not large, ranging from 4 to 10 percentage points. The smaller the effect of the program, the less likely there are to be noticeable differences in the characteristics of the two groups of stayers.
Table 12
The Percentage of Recipients Defined as Stayers,
by Program
SOURCE: MDRC calculations from administrative records from the evaluations listed in Table 1.
Figures 3A and 3B present the results. The differences in demographic characteristics are generally small across programs, with stayers in the control groups generally looking more disadvantaged than their program group counterparts. This pattern is not consistent with the results for the pooled sample, and a look across the individual programs shows that the NEWWS education-focused sample may have dominated the pooled results. For example, in all programs except NEWWS, program group stayers reported fewer barriers to work than control group stayers. The bottom panel of Figure 3B presents differences in the number of months worked during the first three years after random assignment. The two programs with the most generous financial incentives (MFIP and Jobs First) led to the biggest increases in work among stayers.
Figure 3A
Control and Program Group Stayers, by Program:
Demographic Characteristics
SOURCE: MDRC calculations from administrative records and Baseline Information Forms from the evaluations listed in Table 1.
Figure 3B
Control and Program Group Stayers, by Program:
Barriers to Employment
SOURCE: MDRC calculations from administrative records and Private Opinion Surveys from the evaluations listed in Table 1.
Figure 3C
Control and Program Group Stayers, by Program:
Household Income and Material Hardship
SOURCE: MDRC calculations from survey data from the evaluations listed in Table 1.
Figure 3C presents data on stayers’ income and material hardship. The generally low poverty rates in Minnesota (MFIP) and the high rates in Florida (FTP) reflect the differences in welfare benefit levels in these two states. In terms of program-control differences, incomes will differ between the two groups if one is more likely to work than the other or if one receives more generous welfare benefits. The biggest differences in income and poverty are for MFIP, FTP, and Jobs First, where the welfare disregards were the most generous. Program group stayers in Jobs First—with the most generous incentives—were significantly less likely to be poor than their control group counterparts.
In sum, the results show that the welfare-to-work programs in general have not left a group of recipients on the caseload that is more disadvantaged than the group that would have stayed in the absence of the reforms. This may not be very surprising, given that the programs did not produce dramatic increases or decreases in welfare receipt. If anything, the stayers in the incentives programs may have better employment prospects, since they worked more during the follow-up period. The incentives programs also left stayers better off economically than their control group counterparts. Although this may not be related to the ability to eventually leave welfare, increasing incomes for low-income families can have a range of other positive benefits (Knox, Miller, and Gennetian, 2000).
Conclusions
This report uses data from several evaluations of welfare-to-work programs to divide the caseload into three groups: leavers, stayers, and cyclers. The study finds that people who leave welfare and stay off long term differ in a range of expected ways from people who stay on welfare persistently. These leavers are more educated, for example, and they face fewer other potential barriers to work. They had somewhat higher incomes than stayers, but most were still poor or near-poor. They were also more likely to have problems with access to health care. The results highlight the importance of access to post-welfare services, particularly (1) skill-building and
retention services to help former recipients move into better-paying jobs over time and (2) help in obtaining other benefits for which they are eligible, such as Food Stamps and health insurance. These types of services may be especially helpful for people who leave welfare because of reaching a time limit.
Somewhat surprisingly, the group defined as cyclers looks similar to the leaver group in terms of demographic characteristics and barriers to employment. One-third of the people in the cycler group had only one short welfare spell during the period. Nonetheless, the remaining cyclers, who had multiple welfare spells, also look more like leavers than stayers. It is encouraging that these cyclers do not face more barriers to work than other groups, but the results also highlight the need to provide families with services after they leave welfare, so that fewer of them need to return.
About one-third of the people who left welfare were not working when they left, and few of these people went to work in the subsequent year. One caveat to this finding is that work status is defined using administrative records from the Unemployment Insurance system, which misses employment for some workers. Although it is not clear why these people left welfare without work, most of them did not leave for marriage, and many eventually returned to the rolls. Their lack of work appears to be more closely related to the higher number of employment barriers they face. This is another group that needs assistance after leaving welfare—assistance finding and keeping jobs.
Finally, consistent with other recent research, there is little evidence that welfare-to-work programs have affected the composition of the caseload. Stayers in these programs were not more disadvantaged than stayers who were not in the programs. In fact, stayers in the programs with generous financial incentives were better off than other stayers; the incentives allowed more of them to work and still receive benefits, with the result that they had higher incomes. Thus,
enhanced financial incentives, which many states now use, can positively affect the caseload by increasing incomes and increasing work experience. However, most state programs also include time limits, which will eventually turn many stayers into leavers. The findings here show that granting extensions to families who reach a time limit but who have low earnings is one way to ensure that people are, in fact, better off when they leave welfare.
Appendix A
Table A1
Stayers and Leavers:
Demographic Characteristics and Barriers to Employment
SOURCE: MDRC calculations from administrative records, Baseline Information Forms and Private Opinion Surveys from the evaluations listed in Table 1.
NOTES: The analysis is restricted to the individuals in the Program Group.
The data are weighted to reflect the size of the welfare caseload in each state.
Table A2
Stayers and Leavers:
Household Income and Material Hardship
SOURCE: MDRC calculations from survey data from the evaluations listed in Table 1.
NOTES: This analysis is restricted to the individuals in the Program Group.
The data are weighted to reflect the size of the welfare caseload in each state.
References
Acs, Gregory, Pamela Loprest, and Tracy Roberts. 2001. Final Synthesis Report of Findings from ASPE “Leavers” Grants. Washington, DC: The Urban Institute.
Bloom, Dan, Mary Farrell, and Barbara Fink. 2002. Welfare Time Limits: State Policies, Implementation, and Effects on Families. New York: Manpower Demonstration Research Corporation.
Bloom, Dan, James Kemple, Pamela Morris, Susan Scrivener, Nandita Verma, and Richard Hendra. 2000. The Family Transition Program: Final Report on Florida’s Initial Time-Limited Welfare Program. New York: Manpower Demonstration Research Corporation.
Bloom, Dan, Charles Michalopoulos, Johanna Walter, and Patricia Auspos. 1998. WRP: Implementation and Early Impacts of Vermont’s Welfare Restructuring Project. New York: Manpower Demonstration Research Corporation.
Bloom, Dan, Susan Scrivener, Charles Michalopoulos, Pamela Morris, Richard Hendra, Diane Adams-Ciardullo, and Johanna Walter. 2002. Jobs First: Final Report on Connecticut’s Welfare Reform Initiative. New York: Manpower Demonstration Research Corporation.
Brauner, Sarah, and Pamela Loprest. 1999. “Where Are They Now? What States’ Studies of People Who Left Welfare Tell Us.” Assessing the New Federalism. Series A, No. A-32. Washington, DC: The Urban Institute.
Cancian, Maria, Robert Haveman, Daniel Meyer, and Barbara Wolfe. 2000. Before and After TANF: The Economic Well-Being of Women Leaving Welfare. IRP Special Report #77. Madison: University of Wisconsin, Institute for Research on Poverty.
Council of Economic Advisors. 1999. The Effects of Welfare Policy and the Economic Expansion on Welfare Caseloads: An Update. Washington, DC: Council of Economic Advisors.
Danziger, Sandra, Mary Corcoran, Sheldon Danziger, Colleen Heflin, Ariel Kalil, Judith Levine, Daniel Rosen, Kristin Seefeldt, Kristine Siefert, and Richard Tolman. 1999. Barriers to the Employment of Welfare Recipients. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan, Poverty Research and Training Center.
Hamilton, Gayle. 2002. Moving People from Welfare to Work: Lessons from the National Evaluation of Welfare-to-Work Strategies. New York: Manpower Demonstration Research Corporation.
Isaacs, Julia, and Matthew Lyon. 2000. A Cross-State Examination of Families Leaving Welfare: Findings from the ASPE-Funded Leavers Studies. Washington, DC: U.S. Department of Health and Human Services, Office of the Assistant Secretary for Planning and Evaluation, Division of Data and Technical Analysis.
Knox, Virginia, Cynthia Miller, and Lisa Gennetian. 2000. Reforming Welfare and Rewarding Work: A Summary of the Final Report on the Minnesota Family Investment Program. New York: Manpower Demonstration Research Corporation.
Loprest, Pamela. 1999. “Families Who Left Welfare: Who Are They and How Are They Doing?” Assessing the New Federalism. Discussion Paper 99-02. Washington, DC: The Urban Institute.
Loprest, Pamela. 2001. “How Are Families That Left Welfare Doing? A Comparison of Early and Recent Welfare Leavers.” Assessing the New Federalism. Series B, No. B-36. Washington, DC: The Urban Institute,
Loprest, Pamela, and Sheila Zedlewski. 1999. “Current and Former Welfare Recipients: How Do They Differ?” Assessing the New Federalism. Discussion Paper 99-17. Washington, DC: The Urban Institute.
Miller, Cynthia, Cindy Redcross, and Christian Henrichson. 2002. Food Stamp Use Among Former Welfare Recipients. New York: Manpower Demonstration Research Corporation.
Moffitt, Robert, and Jennifer Roff. 2000. “The Diversity of Welfare Leavers.” Welfare, Children & Families: A Three City Study. Policy Brief 00-2. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University.
Oellerich, Donald. 2001. Welfare Reform: Caseload Trends, Program Entrants and Recipients. Washington, DC: U.S. Department of Health and Human Services.
Office of the Assistant Secretary for Planning and Evaluation, U.S. Department of Health and Human Services. 2001.
Status Report on Research on the Outcomes of Welfare Reform. Washington, DC: U.S. Department of Health and Human Services. Available at
http://aspe.hhs.gov/hsp/welf-ref-outcomes01/index.htm.
Wallace, Goeffrey, and Rebecca Blank. 1999. “What Goes Up Must Come Down? Explaining Recent Changes in Public Assistance Caseloads.” In Sheldon Danziger, ed., Economic Condi-Economic Conditions and Welfare Reform. Kalamazoo, MI: Upjohn Institute.
Zedlewski, Sheila, and Donald Anderson. 2001. “Before and After Reform: How Have Families on Welfare Changed?” Assessing the New Federalism. Series B, No. B-32. Washington, DC: The Urban Institute.
.